Krishi
Upaj Mandi Samiti Vs. Orient Paper & Industries Ltd. [1994] INSC 571 (9 November 1994)
Sawant,
P.B. Sawant, P.B. Agrawal, S.C. (J)
CITATION:
1995 SCC (1) 655 JT 1994 (7) 414 1994 SCALE (4)914
ACT:
HEAD NOTE:
The
Judgment of the Court was delivered by SAWANT, J.- The respondent-Orient Paper
Mills (for short `Mills') purchases bamboos as raw material under a contract
with the State Government which holds monopoly in regard to bamboos as a forest
produce in view of the provisions of the M.R Van Upaj (Vyapar Viniyaman) Adhiniyam,
1969 (No. 9 of 1969). The bamboos are supplied to the respondent-Mills by the
Forest Department of the State Government at various forest depots established
for the purpose. After taking delivery from the forest depots, the Mills
transports the same to its factory situated in Amlai in the district of Shahdol
(M.P.). It is not disputed that forest depots from which the Mills purchases
the bamboos fall within the market area of the appellant-Krishi Upaj Mandi Samitis
(for short 'Committees') and the factory of the Mills also falls within the
market area of Krishi Upaj Mandi Samiti, Budhar (M.R).
2.Under
Section 3 of the M.R Krishi Upaj Mandi Adhiniyam, 1973 (for short 'the Act'),
the State Government is empowered to declare by a notification its intention to
establish a market for regulating the purchase and sale of such agricultural
produce and in such area as may be specified in the notification, and invite
objections for the same. Under Section 4 thereof, after the expiry of the
period specified in the notification and after considering the objections and
suggestions as may be necessary, the State Government is authorised to
establish by another notification a market, for the areas specified in the
notification issued under Section 3 or in any portion thereof. Under Section 5,
in every market area, there has to be a market yard and there may be more than
one sub- market yards. For every market yard or sub-market yard, there has to
be a market proper. On the establishment of market under Section 4, Section 6
prohibits local authorities from setting up or establishing or continuing or
using or allowing to be set up, established, continued or used, any place in
the market area for the 658 marketing of any notified agricultural produce.
Likewise, no person is permitted to use any place in the market area for the
marketing of the notified agricultural produce or operate in the market area
any market function otherwise than in accordance with the provisions of the
Act. The exception to this prohibition is in favour of
(a) a
person who himself is a seller of the product concerned, and whose sale does
not exceed four quintals at a time to a person who purchases it for his own
domestic consumption,
(b) produce
which is brought by head loads,
(c) produce
which is purchased or sold by petty traders,
(d) produce
which is imported from outside India,
(e)
produce which is purchased by various fair price shop dealers from the Food
Corporation of India, the Madhya Pradesh State Commodities Trading Corporation
or any other agency or institution authorised by the State Government for
distribution of essential commodities through the public distribution system,
and
(f) the
transfer of the agricultural produce to a cooperative society for the purpose
of securing an advance there from.
3.The Samitis
or Market Committees are established under Section 7 of the Act. Under Section
19(1) of the Act, the Committees have been given power to levy market fees on
notified agricultural produce brought for sale or sold in the market area
tinder their jurisdiction at such rate as may be fixed by the State Government
from time to time subject to the minimum rate of fifty paise and a maximum rate
of two rupees for every one hundred rupees of the price in the manner
prescribed. Under Section 19(2), the market fees are payable by the buyer of
such produce and is not to be deducted from the price payable to the seller. It
is only if the buyer of the produce cannot be identified that all fees are
payable by the seller or by the person who brought the produce for sale in the
market area. Provided further that in case of a commercial transaction between
the traders in the market area, the market fees are to be collected and paid by
the seller. Section 19(6) provides that no notified agricultural produce or any
product processed therefrom shall be removed out of the market proper except in
accordance with a permit issued by the market committee. Sub-section (7)
thereof provides that the market committee may levy and collect entrance fee on
vehicles plying on hire, which may enter into market area at such rate as may
be specified in the bye-laws.
4.Section
31 prohibits any person from operating in the market area in respect of the
notified agricultural produce as commission agent, trader, broker, weighman, hammal,
surveyor, warehouseman, owner or occupier of processing or pressing factories
or as other market functionary except in accordance with the provisions of the
Act and the rules and the bye-laws made there under. Section 32 requires every
person specified in Section 31 who desires to operate in the market area to
apply to the market committee for the grant of a licence. The application has
to be accompanied by such fees as the Director of Marketing appointed by the
State Government may subject to the minimum, prescribe in this behalf. Under
Section 33, the market committee is given power to cancel or suspend the licence
for reasons and under the procedure laid down therein. Section 38 provides for
the 659 constitution of a Market Committee Fund in which all the moneys
received by the market committee are paid and from which all expenditure
incurred by the committee is defrayed.
Section
39 lays down the purposes for which the Market Committee Fund is to be
expended. They are:
"39.
Application of market committee fund.- Subject' to the provisions of Section
38, the market committee fund may be expended for the following purposes only,
namely—
(i)the
acquisition of a site or sites for the market yards;
(ii)the
maintenance and improvement of the market yards;
(iii)the
construction and repairs of buildings necessary for the purposes of the market
and for convenience or safety of the, persons using the market yard;
(iv)the
maintenance of standard weights and measures;
(v)the
meeting of establishment charges including payments and contributions towards
provident fund, pension and gratuity of the officers and servants employed by a
market committee;
(vi)the
payment of interest on the loans that may be raised for the purpose of the
market and provisions of sinking fund in respect of such loans;
(vii)the
collection and dissemination or information, relating to crops statistics and
marketing of agricultural produce;
(viii)(a)
the expenses incurred in auditing the accounts of the market committee;
(b)
payment of honorarium to Chairman, travelling allowance of Chairman, Vice-
Chairman and other members of the market committee and sitting fees payable to
members for attending the meeting;
(c) contribution
to State Marketing Development Fund;
(d) meeting
any expenditure for carrying out order of 'the State Government and any other
work entrusted to market committee under any other Act;
(e) contribution
to any scheme for increasing agriculturists in the market area;
(f)to
develop necessary infrastructure within a radius of one kilometre from the
market yard/sub-market yard for facilitating the flow of notified agricultural
produce with the prior sanction of the Director and with the prior permission
of the local authority concerned for using their land for this purpose;
(g) to
provide for development of agricultural produce in the market area;
(h) payment
of expenses on elections under this Act.
660
(ix) any
other purpose whereon the expenditure to the market committee fund is in the
public interest, subject to the prior sanction of the State Government."
5.
Section 43 provides for the constitution of a Market Development Fund and every
market committee is required to pay every three months, to the Marketing Board
constituted under the Act such percentage not exceeding 50 per cent of its
gross receipts comprising of licensing fees and market fees as the State
Government may by notification declare from time to time. All expenditure
incurred by the Board according to the object sanctioned by it has to be
defrayed out of the said fund.
6. It
appears that the Committees levied fees on the sale and purchase of bamboos.
The Mills challenged the said levy by way of a writ petition in the M.R High
Court on the ground that the Act was ultra vires the Constitution, that the
requirement of obtaining the licence under Section 32 and of paying the market
fee under Section 19 of the Act was also unconstitutional.
7. The
High Court relied upon a decision of the same Court in Miscellaneous Petition
No. 4063 of 1986 decided on 12-1- 1988 and allowed the writ petition. The High
Court by the said decision of 12-1-1988 had repelled the challenges to the
constitutional validity of the Act and its provisions, but had upheld the
contention of the petitioners that the levy was not justified on the ground
that it was not established that any direct or indirect benefit was conferred
either on the purchasers or traders of bamboos as a class by the market
committee. For the purpose, the High Court relied upon a decision in Om Parkash
Agarwal v. Giri Raj Kishoril. The High Court further held that in view of the
return filed on behalf of the State Government, while selling the bamboos, the
Forest Department would be a trader within the meaning of the Act and hence the
sale of bamboos by the State Government to the petitioners would be a sale of a
notified agricultural produce by a trader to a trader and in such a case the
second proviso to subsection (2) of Section 19 of the Act will be attracted.
That proviso contemplates that in case of a commercial transaction between
traders in the market area, the market fee shall be collected and paid by the
seller. Consequently, according to the High Court, even if it was accepted for
the sake of argument, that market fee on sale of bamboos by the State
Government to the petitioner was leviable, it was not to be paid through the
Market Committees by the petitioners who are the buyers; but it has to be
collected and paid by the Forest Department of the State Government. Hence, the
Market Committees cannot require the petitioners to pay the market fee directly
to them. While allowing the present writ petition on this ground, the Court
also observed as follows:
"At
this place, however, we wish to make it clear that if in future any service is
rendered by any market committee with regard to transactions of sale and
purchase in the various forest depots it would be open to the concerned market
committee to lay a claim to levy market fee in the 1 (1986) 1 SCC 722: AIR 1986
SC 726 661 changed circumstances. It is further made clear that since that
contingency is not stated to have so far arisen in these cases, we are not
expressing any opinion with regard to any claim about market fee that may be
made by the concerned market committee, if any of the paper mills actually
sells some stock of bamboos as contemplated by the M.P. Van Upaj (Vyapar Viniyaman)
Sanshodhan Adhiniyam, 1986 (No. 15 of 1987)." 8.We are not concerned in
this appeal with the vires of the Act or of the levies of the market fees or of
the requirement of a licence and of the payment of the licence fees since those
contentions are not raised before us on behalf of the Mills and they have been
expressly given up.
There
is also no cross-appeal on the said point. The limited controversy before us is
whether the finding of the High Court that the levy of the market fees is not
justified because there is no direct or indirect benefit conferred by the
market committee either on the purchasers or traders of bamboos as a class, is
valid or not.
9.We
may now refer to the authorities cited at the bar.
The
earliest decision of this Court on the definition of 'fee' and 'tax' and the
distinction between the two is of the Constitution Bench of seven learned
Judges in Commissioner, Hindu Religious Endowments v. Sri Lakshmindra Thirtha Swamiar
of Sri Shirur Mutt2. It was observed then that though levying of fee is only a
particular form of the exercise of the taxing power of the State, our
Constitution has placed fee under a separate category for purposes of
legislation, and at the end of each one of the three Legislative Lists, it has
given power to the particular legislature to legislate on the imposition of fee
in respect of every one of the items dealt with in the list itself.
Referring
then to the definition of 'tax', the Court referred to the decision of the
Australian High Court in Matthews v. Chicory Marketing Board3. There 'tax' is
defined as a compulsory exaction of money by public authority for public
purposes enforceable by law and is not payment for services rendered. The Court
then observed that the essence of taxation is compulsion, that is to say, it is
imposed under statutory power without the taxpayer's consent and the payment is
enforced by law. The second characteristic of tax according to the Court is
that it is an imposition made for public purpose without reference to any
special benefit to be conferred on the payer of the tax.
The
levy of tax is for the purposes of general revenue which when collected forms
part of the public revenue of the State. There is no quid pro quo between the
taxpayer and the public authority. It is a part of the common burden and the
quantum of imposition upon the taxpayer depends generally upon his capacity to
pay. Referring to the definition of 'fee', the Court observed that a fee is
generally defined to be a charge for a special service rendered to individuals
by some governmental agency. The amount of fee levied is supposed to be based
on the expenses incurred by the Government in rendering the service though in 2
1954 SCR 1005 : AIR 1954 SC 282 3 (1938) 60 CLR 263 (Aus HC) 662 some cases the
costs are arbitrarily assessed. Ordinarily, the fees are uniform and no account
is taken of the varying abilities of different recipients to pay. These are
some of the general characteristics of fee but as there may be various kinds of
fees, it is not possible to formulate a definition that would be applicable to
all cases. The Court then referred to the contention with regard to the
distinction between a tax and a fee in the compulsory nature of the former and
the voluntary nature of the latter and observed that a careful examination will
reveal that the element of compulsion or coerciveness is present in all kinds
of impositions though in different degrees and that it is not totally absent in
fees. Hence it cannot be the sole or even a material criterion for
distinguishing a tax from fee. Compulsion lies in the fact that payment is
enforceable by law against a man in spite of his unwillingness or want of
consent and this element is present in taxes as well as in fees. In some cases
whether a man would come within the category of a service receiver may be a
matter of his choice, but that by itself could not constitute a major test
which can be taken as the criterion of these species of imposition. The
distinction between a tax and a fee lies primarily in the fact that a tax is
levied as a part of the common burden while a fee is a payment for a special
benefit or privilege. Fees confer a special capacity although the special
advantage is secondary to the primary motive of regulation in the public
interest.
Public
interest seems to be at the basis of all impositions but in a fee it is some
special benefit which the individual receives. The special benefit accruing to
the individual is the reason for payment in the case of fees. In the case of a
tax, the particular advantage if it exists at all, is an incidental result of
State action. A fee is a sort of return or consideration for services rendered
and hence it is primarily necessary that the levy of fee should on the face of
the legislative provision be correlated to the expenses incurred by Government
in rendering the services.
As
indicated in Article 110(2) of the Constitution, ordinarily there are two
classes of cases where Government imposes fees upon persons. In the first class
of cases, Government simply grants a permission or privilege to a person to do
something which otherwise that person would not be competent to do, and
extracts fees either heavy or moderate from that person in return for the
privilege that is conferred. A most common illustration of this type of cases
is furnished by the licence fees for motor vehicles.
Here
the costs incurred by the Government in maintaining an office or bureau for the
granting of licences may be very small and the amount of imposition that is
levied is based really not upon the costs incurred by the Government but upon
the benefit that the individual receives. In such cases, the tax element is
predominant and if the money paid by licence-holders goes for the upkeep of
roads and other matters of general public utility, the licence fee cannot but
be regarded as a tax. In the other class of cases, the Government does some
positive work for the benefit of persons, and the money is taken as the return
for the work done or services rendered. If the money thus paid is set apart and
appropriated specifically for the performance of such work and is not merged in
the public revenues for the benefit of the general public, it could 663 be
counted as fees and not a tax. There is really no generic difference between
tax and fee, and the taxing power of a State may manifest itself in three
different forms known respectively as special assessments, fees and taxes.
Our
Constitution has for legislative purposes made a distinction between a tax and
a fee and, as stated above, while there are various entries in the Legislative
Lists with regard to various forms of taxes, there is an entry at the end of
each one of the three lists as regards fees which could be levied in respect of
any of the matters that is included in it. The implication seems to be that fee
has special reference to Government action undertaken in respect of any of
those matters.
10.In Mahant
Sri Jagannath Ramanuj Das v. State of Orissa4 the Constitution Bench of five
learned Judges upheld the annual contribution provided in Section 49 of the Orissa
Hindu Endowments Act, 1939 as fee on the same reasoning as in the earlier
decision of seven learned Judges.
11.In Ratilal
Panachand Gandhi v. State of Bombay5 the validity of the contribution imposed
under Section 58 of the Bombay Public Trust Act, 1950 fell for consideration.
The Court held that as the contribution was levied purely for the purposes of
due administration of the trust property- and to defray the expenses incurred
in connection with the same, no objection could be taken to the provisions of
the section on the ground of its infringing the fundamental rights of the
appellants. The Court referred to its earlier decision in Shirur Mutt case2 and
the observations made and principles laid down there and reiterated the same.
12.In Hingir-Rampur
Coal Co. Ltd. v. State of Orissa6 the Constitution Bench of five learned Judges
reiterated that although there can be no generic difference between a tax and
fee since both are compulsory exaction of money by public authorities, there is
this distinction between them that whereas the tax is imposed for public
purposes and requires no consideration to support it, a fee is levied
essentially for services rendered and there must be an element of quid pro quo
between the person who pays it and the public authority that imposes it. While
a tax invariably goes into the consolidated fund, a fee is earmarked for the
specified services in a fund created for the purpose. Whether a cess is one or
the other would naturally depend on the facts of each case. If in the guise of
a fee, the legislature imposes a tax, it is for the court on a scrutiny of the
scheme of the levy to determine its real character. The distinction is recognised
by the Constitution which while empowering the appropriate legislatures to levy
taxes under the entries in the three lists refers to their power to levy fee in
respect of any such matters, except the fees taken in court. In determining
whether the levy is a fee, the true test must be whether its primary and
essential purpose is to render specific services to a specified area or class,
it being of no consequence that the State may ultimately and indirectly be
benefited by it. The amount of the 4 1954 SCR 1046: AIR 1954 SC 400 5 1954 SCR 1055
: AIR 1954 SC 388 6 (1961) 2 SCR 537 : AIR 1961 SC 459 664 levy must depend on
the extent of the services sought to be rendered and if they are proportionate,
it would be unreasonable to say that since the impost is high, it must be a
duty of excise. Nor can the method prescribed by the legislature for recovering
the levy by itself alter its character. The method is a matter of convenience
and though relevant, has to be tested in the light of other relevant
circumstances.
13.In
H.H. Sadhundra Thirtha Swamiar v. Commissioner for Hindu Religious and
Charitable Endowments7 the Constitution Bench of five learned Judges on the
same reasoning as in the earlier decision of seven learned Judges in Shirur
Mutt case2 upheld the contributions levied under the amended Section 76(1) of
the Madras Religious Endowments Act, 1951 as fee since the said contributions
went into a separate fund and not the consolidated fund of the State and were
earmarked for defraying the expenses for rendering services.
The
contributions were not even payable to the Government but to the Commissioner
and hence they were not levied as a tax but only as a fee. It was observed
further that a fee does not cease to be of that character merely because, there
is an element of compulsion in it nor is it a postulate of a fee that it must
have relation to the actual service rendered. Absence of uniformity is not a
criterion on which alone it can be said that the levy is of the nature of a
tax. The legislature has power to enact appropriate retrospective legislation
declaring levies as fees by denuding them of the characteristics of tax.
14.In Corpn.
of Calcutta v. Liberty Cinema8 the facts were that under Section 413 of the
Calcutta Municipal Act, 195 1, no person was permitted to keep open any cinema
house for public amusement without a licence granted by the Municipal
Corporation. Under Section 548(2), for every licence under the Act, a fee could
be charged at such rates as may from time to time be fixed by the Corporation.
In 1948, the appellant-Corporation fixed fees on the basis of annual valuation
of the cinema house and it was paid by the respondent. In 1958, the appellant
changed the basis of assessment of the fee and levied it at rates prescribed
per show according to the sanctioned seating capacity of the cinema house. The
respondent-cinema, therefore, moved the High Court by a writ petition and the
petition was allowed.
In
appeal to this Court, the appellant-Corporation contended that (i) the levy was
a tax and not a fee in return for services, and (ii) Section 548(2) did not
suffer from the vice of excessive delegation. On behalf of the respondent, it
was contended that (i) the levy was a fee in return for the services to be
rendered and not a tax, and since it was not commensurate with the costs
incurred by the Corporation in providing the services, the levy was invalid;
(ii) if Section 548 authorised a levy of tax as distinct- from fee, it was
invalid as it amounted to illegal delegation of legislative function to the
appellant to fix the amount of tax without any guidance for the purpose, and
(iii) the levy was invalid as violating Articles 19(1)(f) and (g) of the
Constitution. By 7 1963 Supp 2 SCR 302: AIR 1963 SC 966 8 (1965) 2 SCR 477: AIR
1965 SC 1107 665 majority, it was held that the levy was not a fee but a tax.
While
dealing with the difference between tax and a fee in this context, the Court
referred to the earlier decisions of this Court, viz., Commissioner, Hindu
Religious Endowments v. Sri Lakshmindra Thirtha Swamiar of Sri Shirur Mutt2, Hingir-Rampur
Coal Co. Ltd. v. State of Orissa6 and H.H. Sadhundra Thirtha Swamiar v.
Commissioner for Hindu Religious and Charitable Endowments7 and observed that the
decisions of this Court established that in order to make a levy a fee for
services rendered, the levy must confer special benefit on the persons on whom
it is imposed.
15.In Kewal
Krishna Puri v. State of Punjab9 where the levy of market fees by the market
committees, as in the present case, though under a different Act, viz., the
Punjab Agricultural Produce Markets Act, 1961 specifically fell for
consideration before the Constitution Bench of five learned Judges, it was held
that the impost of fee and the liability to pay it is on a particular
individual or a class of individuals. They are under the obligation to submit
accounts, returns or the like to the authorities concerned in cases where
quantification of the amount of fee depends upon the same. They have to undergo
the botheration and harassment, sometimes justifiably and sometimes
unjustifiably, in the process of discharging their liability to pay the fee.
The authorities levying the fee deal with them and realise the fee from them.
By operation of the economic laws in certain kinds of imposition of fee, the
burden may be passed on to different other persons one after the other. In that
case, the market committees and the market boards assume to themselves the
liberty of utilising and spending the realisations from market fees to a
considerable extent as if it was a tax although in reality it was not so. It
was further held that rendering some service, however remote the service may
be, cannot, strictly speaking, satisfy the element of quid pro quo, required to
be established in cases of the impost of fee. Registration fee, however, had to
be taken to stand on a different footing altogether. In the case of such a fee,
the test of quid pro quo is not to be satisfied with such close or proximate relationship
as in the case of many other fees.
By and
large, the registration fee is charged as a regulatory measure. The Court then
culled the following principles from the conspectus of various authorities on
the subject: (SCR pp. 1243-1244 : SCC pp. 434-35, para 23) (i)That the amount
of fee realised must be earmarked for rendering services to the licensees in
the notified market area and a good and substantial portion of it must be shown
to be expended for this purpose.
* * *
(iii)That while rendering services in the market area for the purpose of
facilitating the transactions of purchase and sale with a view to achieve the
objects of the marketing legislation it is not necessary to confer the whole of
the benefit on the licensees but some special 9 (1980) 1 SCC 416: (1979) 3 SCR
1217 666 benefits must be conferred on them which have a direct, Close, and
reasonable correlation between the licensees and the transactions.
(iv)That
while conferring some special benefits on the licensees it is permissible to render
such service in the market which may be in the general interest of all
concerned with the transactions taking place in the market.
(v)
That spending the amount of market fees for the purpose of augmenting the
agricultural produce, its facility of transport in villages and to provide
other facilities meant mainly or exclusively for the benefit of the
agriculturists is not permissible on the ground that such service in the long
run go to increase the volume of transactions in the market ultimately benefiting
the traders also.
Such
an indirect and remote benefit to the traders is in no sense a special benefit
to them.
(vi)That
the element of quid pro quo may not be possible, or even necessary, to be
established with arithmetical exactitude but even broadly and reasonably it
must be established by the authorities who charge the fees that the amount is
being spent for rendering services to those on whom falls the burden of the
fee.
(vii)At
least a good and substantial portion of the amount collected on account of
fees, may be in the neighbourhood of two-thirds or three-fourths, must be shown
with reasonable certainty as being spent for rendering services of the kind
mentioned above.
Referring
to the provisions of the impugned Act, the Court further held that the whole
object of the Act was to supervise and control the transaction of purchase by
the traders from the agriculturists in order to prevent exploitation of the
latter by the former. The supervision and control could be effective only in
specified localities and places and not throughout the extensive market area.
The
fee levied was not on the agricultural produce in the sense of imposing any
kind of tax or duty on the agricultural produce. Nor was it a tax on the
transaction of purchase or sale. The levy was an impost on the buyer of the
agricultural produce in the market in relation to transaction of his purchase.
The agriculturists were not required to share any portion of the burden of this
fee. In case the buyer was not a licensee, the responsibility of paying the fee
was of the seller who may realise the same from the buyer. But such a
contingency could not arise in respect of the transaction of a sale by an
agriculturist of his agricultural produce in the market to a dealer who must be
a licensee. Probably such an alternative provision was meant to be made for
outside buyers who were not licensees when they bought their agricultural
produce from or through the licensees. Every market committee was obliged under
sub-section (2)(a) of Section 27 of that Act to pay out of its fund to the
marketing board as contribution such percentage of its income derived from licence
fee, market fee and fines levied by the courts as specified therein.
The
purpose of this contribution was to enable the Board to defray expenses of the
office establishment of the 667 Board and such other expense incurred by it in
the interests of the Committees in general. The purposes for which the
Marketing Development Fund might be expended were enumerated in Section 26 and
the purpose for which the Market Committee Funds might be expended were
catalogued in Section 28 of that Act. The whole of the State was divided into
market areas. The propaganda in favour of agricultural improvement and
expenditure for production and betterment of agricultural produce would be in
the general interest of agriculture in the market area. It was not permissible
to spend the market fees realised from the traders for any purpose calculated
to promote the national or public interest. No market committee could be
permitted to utilise the fund for an ulterior purpose, however benevolent,
laudable and charitable the object might be. The whole concept of fee would
collapse if the amount realised by the market committees could be permitted to
be spent in that fashion. Technically and legally one may not have any
objection to the expenditure of such money for the purposes mentioned in
clauses (x), (xi), (xiii) and (xvii). The Court also held that it was not
necessary to strike down any clauses of Section 28 as being unconstitutional
merely on the ground that the expenditure authorised therein went beyond the
purposes of the utilisation of market fees.
However,
where a concrete case comes where the spending of money cannot be reasonably
connected with the purposes for which the market fee can be spent, the courts
may have to deal with the question as to whether such expenditure can be met
from the market fees realised. The State Agricultural Marketing Board
constituted under the Act is the central controlling and superintending
authority over all the marketing committees, the primary function of which is
to render services in the market. Parting with thirty per cent of the income by
a market committee in favour of the Board is not so excessive or unreasonable so
as to warrant the interference on the ground of violation of the principle of
quid pro quo in the utilisation of the market fee. The Marketing Development
Fund can be validly spent for the purposes mentioned in clauses (i), (ii),
(iii), (iv), first part of clauses (v), (vi), (vii), (viii), (ix), (xii), the
first part of clauses (xiii), (xiv), (xv) and (xvi). The fund cannot be
expended for the purposes mentioned in the second part of clause (v), clauses
(x), (xi), the second part of clause (xiii) and clause (xvii). The purpose of
the law will be served by restricting the operation of Section 26 to the
purposes for which it could be validly spent. It is not necessary to strike
down the provisions of Section 26 for that purpose. The market fee cannot be spent
on the construction of link roads although transportation is very essential for
the development of a market and to enable the growers of the agricultural
produce to bring the same to the market. The impost must be correlated with the
service to be rendered to the payers of the fees as pointed out above.
If
insecticides and pesticides are for use at the place where actually the
marketing operations are carried on, it would be justifiable expenditure. But
if they are meant to be supplied to the agriculturists for use at their village
homes or in their fields, the market fee cannot be spent for the purpose. The
charging of fee at the rate of Rs 2 per Rs 100 was not considered
unjustifiable. The Court observed 668 that any increase in the rate should be corelated
to the expenditure made strictly for the purposes mentioned above.
16. It
may be mentioned here that the purposes mentioned in Sections 26 and 28 of the
Punjab Agricultural Produce Marketing Act which fell for consideration there
are similar to the provisions of the M.P. Krishi Upaj Mandi Adhiniyam, 1973.
17. In
Southern Pharmaceuticals & Chemicals v. State of Kerala10 which is a
decision of three learned Judges, what fell for consideration was the validity
of the levy of supervisory charges under the Kerala Abkari Act, 1967. In this
connection, it was observed that it was increasingly realised that merely
because the collections for the services rendered or grant of a privilege or licence,
are taken to the Consolidated Fund of the State and are not separately
appropriated towards the expenditure for rendering the service is not by itself
decisive of the nature of the levy. That is because the Constitution did not
contemplate it to be an essential element of a fee that it should be credited
to a separate fund and not to the Consolidated Fund. It was also increasingly realised
that the element of quid pro quo stricto sensu was not always a sine qua non of
a fee. The Court therefore, observed that it is needless to stress that the
element of quid pro quo was not necessarily absent in every tax. The Court then
quoted with approval the observations of Seervai in his Constitutional Law on Shirur
Mutt case2 that the attention of this Court does not appear to have been drawn
to Article 266 which requires that all revenues of the Union of India and the
States must go into the respective Consolidated Funds and all other public
moneys must go into the respective accounts of the Union and the States. If the
services rendered are not by a separate body like the Charity Commissioner, by
a Government Department, the character of imposition could not change because
under Article 266, the moneys collected for the services rendered must be
credited to the Consolidated Fund. After referring to the decision in Kewal Krishan
Puri case9, the Court observed that the observations made in that case, viz.,
the element of quid pro quo must be established, were not intended and meant as
laying down a rule of universal application. In that case, the Court was
considering the rate of market fee and whether the increase in the rate from Rs
2 for every Rs 100 to Rs 3 was justified. There was no material placed to
justify the increase in the rate of fee and, therefore, the Court took the view
there that it partook the nature of a tax. The Court thus observed that it
seems the Court in that case, proceeded on the assumption that the element of
quid pro quo must always be present in fee but the traditional concept of quid
pro quo was undergoing a transformation. The question of corelationship between
services rendered and the fee levied was essentially a question of fact.
18.In Sreenivasa
General Traders v. State of A.P II a Bench of three learned Judges considered
the validity of a levy of market fee under the 10 (1981) 4 SCC 391 : 1981 SCC (Tax)
320: (1982) 1 SCR 519 11 (1983) 4 SCC 353 :(1983) 3 SCR 843 669 Andhra Pradesh
(Agricultural Produce and Livestock) Market Act, 1966. The Court held that the
provisions of Section 7(6) of that Act which prohibited any person purchasing,
producing or selling any notified agricultural produce, livestock and products
of livestock in a notified market area but outside the market in that area were
valid having regard to the purpose and object of the legislation. The Court
further held that the levy of market fee under Section 12(1) of that Act on the
transactions effected by the petitioners from their business premises located
in the notified market area but outside the market proper was legal. The
petitioners' contention to the contrary proceeded on the wrong assumption
because, firstly, in view of the express prohibition contained in Section 7(6)
of the Act, the petitioners could not carry on such a trade without resorting
to the market proper. The contravention of Section 7(6) was penally an offence
under Section 23(1) of that Act. Secondly, the establishment of regulated
market for agricultural produce is a service rendered to those who are engaged
in the business of purchase and sale of such commodity. That duty of the market
committee does not end with the establishment of markets but extends under
Section 15 of that Act to providing facilities in the market. The service
rendered by market committees and facilities so provided are not confined to
the market proper but extends to the notified area. The Court held by referring
to Kewal Krishan Puri case9 that there was no substance in the contention of
the petitioner that since the market committees do not provide any additional
facilities to justify increase in the rate in the market fee, the increase was illegal.
The Court pointed out that the said decision does not lay down any legal
principle of general applicability and was clearly distinguishable on the
facts.
According
to the Court, in that case, the increase in the market fee was quashed because
the income of the market fee had become a source of revenue. The market
committees throughout the State were left with huge surplus funds and the State
Government had directed the market committees to contribute a large sum of
money to a medical college and deposit the surplus amount with the State
Agricultural Marketing Board, and the Board in turn advanced interest- free
loans to marketing federations. Even after incurring the said unauthorised
expenditure, the market committees were left with huge surplus and were
required to make donations to many educational institutions. The marketing
committees also spent large sums on general improvement of the municipal area.
The Punjab Act permitted diversion of funds for any purpose calculated to
promote the general interest of the committees or the national or public
interest. The Court further observed that the traditional view that there must
be quid pro quo for a fee had undergone a sea change. The distinction between a
tax and fee lies primarily in the fact that a tax is levied as a part of the
common burden while a fee is for payment of a specific benefit or privilege
although the special advantage is secondary to the primary duty of regulating
any public interest. If the element of revenue for general purpose of the State
predominates, the levy becomes a tax. In regard to fees, there is and must
always be a correlation between the fee collected and the services intended to
be rendered.
In
determining 670 whether the levy is a fee or tax, the true test must be whether
its primary and essential purpose is to render specific services to a specified
area or class. It may be of no consequence that the State may ultimately and
indirectly be benefited by it. The power of any legislature to levy a fee is
conditioned by the fact that it must be by and large a quid pro quo for
services rendered. Every corelationship between the levy and the services
rendered is one of general character and not a mathematical exactitude.
All
that is necessary is that there should be a reasonable relationship between the
levy of fee and the services rendered. There is no postulate of a fee that it
must have a direct relation to the actual services rendered by the authority to
each individual to obtain the benefit of the service. It is now increasingly realised
that merely because the collections for the services rendered or for grant of a
privilege or licence are taken to the Consolidated Fund of the State and not
separately appropriated towards the expenditure for rendering the service, is
not by itself decisive of the nature of the levy whether it is a fee or a tax.
The Court further held that presumably, the attention of the Court in the Shirur
Mutt case2 was not drawn to Article 266 of the Constitution. The Constitution
nowhere contemplates it to be an essential element of a fee that it should be
credited to a separate fund and not to the Consolidated Fund. The element of
quid pro quo in the strict sense is not always sine qua non for a fee. The
element of quid pro quo is not necessarily absent in every tax. The Court
further held that the increase in the rate of market fee in that case from 50 paise
to Re 1 was not illegal on the ground that there was no corelation between the
increase and the services rendered. The levy of market fee was corelated to the
purposes mentioned in Section 15 of that Act. All the moneys received by a
market committee from the traders on sale of agricultural produce had to be
paid into a fund called the Market Committee Fund and all expenditure incurred
had to be defrayed out of that fund and any surplus had to be invested in the
prescribed manner. The purposes mentioned in Section 15 of that Act are all
purposes which were extremely beneficial to the growers and the traders. The
increase was justified also because the cost of rendering services had
correspondingly increased over the years. Moreover, the market committees are
rendering services some of which were obligatory duties.
The
Court also held that it is not always possible to work out in mathematical
precision the amount of fee required for the services to be rendered each year
and to collect just that amount which was sufficient for meeting the
expenditure in that year. In some years, the income of the market committee by
way of market fee and licence fee may exceed the expenditure and in another
year when the development works are in progress for providing modem
infrastructure facilities, the expenditure may be far in excess of the income.
It is wrong to take any one particular year or a few years into consideration
to decide whether the fee is commensurate with the services rendered. An
overall view has to be taken in dealing with the question whether there is quid
pro quo.
19. In
Om Parkash Agarwal v. Giri Raj Kishoril what fell for consideration was the cess
imposed under Section 3 of the Haryana Rural 671 Development Fund Act, 1983.
The cess was imposed on ad valorem basis at the rate of one per cent of the
sale proceeds of the agricultural produce brought or sold or brought for
processing in a notified market area. The dealer in his turn, was entitled to
pass on the burden of the cess paid by him to the next purchaser of the
agricultural produce from him. Section 4(1) of the Act provided for the
creation of the fund called the Haryana Rural Development Fund which was vested
in the State Government and the amount of cess was to be credited to the said
fund. Sub-section (5) of Section 4 of the Act stated that the fund would be
applied by the State Government to meet the expenditure incurred in the rural
areas in connection with the development of roads, hospitals, means of
communication, water supply, sanitation facilities and for the welfare of
agricultural labour or for any other scheme approved by the State Government
for the development of the rural areas. This Court held that the Act was
unconstitutional since the State Legislature was not competent to enact it. The
Court held that in the guise of a fee, the legislation imposed a tax. It was
constitutionally impermissible for the State to do so. The Court pointed out
that in the present case, the definition of expression "rural areas"
was vague. There was no specification in the Act that the amount or a
substantial part of the amount collected by way of cess would be spent on any
public purposes within the market area where the dealer was carrying on his
business. The purpose for which the fund could be spent was the same on which
any amount collected by way of ax was spent by any State and there was nothing
which was done specially to benefit the dealer.
When
any amount was spent from the fund, the interest of the dealers was not at all
kept in view even generally. The cess, therefore, partook the character or part
of the common burden which had to be levied and collected only as a tax.
A
dealer who paid the cess may, as one of the members of the general public,
derive some benefit from the expenditure.
The
benefit so derived by him was merely incidental to the fact that he happens to
be a person residing in the State of Haryana. It was not the same as the
benefit which a dealer in a market area would derive from the expenditure of
the fund by a market committee or as the benefit which a person living in a
town would derive by the expenditure incurred by the municipality concerned.
There was practically no difference between the Consolidated Fund and the fund
both of which could be spent practically on any public purpose almost
throughout the State. In such a situation, it was difficult to hold that there
existed any corelation between the amount paid by way of cess under the Act and
the services rendered to a person from whom it was collected.
20.In Kishan
Lal Lakhmi Chand v. State of Haryana12 which is a decision of a Bench of three
learned Judges, the levy of cess under the Haryana Rural Development Act, 1986
fell for consideration. The Court held that from the scheme of the Act, it
would be clear that there is a broad, reasonable and general corelationship
between the levy and the resultant 12 1993 Supp (4) SCC 461 : 1993 Supp 4 SCR
461 672 benefit to the producer of the agricultural produce, dealer and
purchasers as a class though no single payer of the fee receives direct or
personal benefit from those services.
Though
the general public may be benefited from some of the services like laying
roads, the primary service was to the producer, dealer and purchaser of the
agricultural produce.
The
Court also held that the power of any legislature to levy a fee is conditioned
by the fact that it must be by and large quid pro quo for the services
rendered. However, corelationship between the levy and the services
rendered/expected is one of general character and not of mathematical
exactitude. All that is necessary is that there should be reasonable
relationship between the levy of the fee and the services rendered. The Court
then held that the cess levied therein is a fee and that the levy for the fund
was created to expend for the purposes enumerated under Section 6(5) of the
Act.
21.Thus
what emerges from the conspectus of the aforesaid decisions is as follows:
(1)Though
levying of fee is only a particular form of the exercise of the taxing power of
the State, our Constitution has placed fee under a separate category for
purposes of legislation. At the end of each one of the three Legislative Lists,
it has given power to the particular legislature to legislate on the imposition
of fee in respect of every one of the items dealt with in the list itself,
except fees taken in Court.
(2)The
tax is a compulsory exaction of money by public authority for public purposes
enforceable by law and is not payment for services rendered. There is no quid
pro quo between the taxpayer and the public authority.
It is
a part of the common burden and the quantum of imposition upon the taxpayer
depends generally upon his capacity to pay.
(3)Fee
is a charge for a special service rendered to individuals or a class by some
governmental agency. The amount of fee levied is supposed to be based on the
expenses incurred by the Government in rendering the service though in some
cases the costs are arbitrarily assessed. Ordinarily, the fees are uniform and
no account is taken of the varying abilities of different recipients to pay.
These are various kinds of fees and it is not possible to formulate a
definition that would be applicable to all cases.
(4)The
element of compulsion or coerciveness is present in all kinds of impositions
though in different degrees and it is not totally absent in fees. Hence it
cannot be the sole or even a material criterion for distinguishing a tax from
fee.
Compulsion
lies in the fact that payment is enforceable by law against an individual in
spite of his unwillingness or want of consent and this element is present in
taxes as well as in fees.
(5)The
distinction between a tax and a fee lies primarily in the fact that a tax is
levied as a part of the common burden while a fee is a payment for a special
benefit or privilege. Fees confer a special capacity although the special
advantage is secondary to the primary motive of 673 regulation in the public
interest. Public interest seems to be at the basis of all impositions but in a
fee it is some special benefit which is conferred and accruing which is the
reason for imposition of the levy. In the case of a tax, the particular
advantage if it exists at all, is an incidental result of State action. A fee
is a sort of return or consideration for services rendered and hence it is
primarily necessary that the levy of fee should on the face of the legislative
provision be corelated to the expenses incurred by Government in rendering the
services. As indicated in Article 110(2) of the Constitution ordinarily there
are two classes of cases where Government imposes fees upon persons. The first
is of grant of permission or privilege and the second for services rendered. In
the first class of cases, the cost incurred by the Government for granting of
permission or privilege may be very small and the amount of imposition levied
is based not necessarily upon the costs incurred by the Government but upon the
benefit that the individual receives. In such cases, the tax element is
predominant. If the money paid by privilegeholders goes entirely for the
expenses of matters of general public utility, the fee cannot but be regarded
as a tax. In the other class of cases, the Government does some positive work
for the benefit of persons and the money is taken as the return for the work
done or services rendered.
(6)There
is really no generic difference between tax and fee and the taxing power of the
State may manifest itself in three different forms, viz., special assessments,
fees and taxes. Whether a cess is tax or fee, would depend upon the facts of
each case. If in the guise of fee, the legislature imposes a tax it is for the
Court on a scrutiny of the scheme of the levy, to determine its real character.
In determining whether the levy is a fee, the true test must be whether its
primary and essential purpose is to render specific services to a specific area
or classes. It is of no consequence that the State may ultimately and indirectly
be benefited by it. The amount of the levy must depend upon the extent of the
services sought to be rendered and if they are proportionate, it would be
unreasonable to say that since the impost is high it must be a tax. Nor can the
method prescribed by the legislature for recovering the levy by itself alter
its character. The method is a matter of convenience and though relevant, has
to be tested in the light of other relevant circumstances.
(7)It
is not a postulate of a fee that it must have relation to the actual service
rendered. However, the rendering of service has to be established. The service,
further, cannot be remote. The test of quid pro quo is not to be satisfied with
close or proximate relationship in all kinds of fees. A good and substantial
portion of the fee must, however, be shown to be expended for the purpose for
which the fee is levied. It is not necessary to confer the whole of the benefit
on the payers of the fee but some special benefit must be conferred on them
which has a direct and reasonable corelation to the fee. While conferring some
special benefits on the payers of the fees, it is permissible to render service
in 674 the general interest of all concerned. The element of quid pro quo is
not possible or even necessary to be established with arithmetical exactitude.
But it must be established broadly and reasonably that the amount is being
spent for rendering services to those on whom the burden of the fee falls.
There
is no postulate of a fee that it must have a direct relation to the actual
services rendered by the authorities to each individual to obtain the benefit
of the service. The element of quid pro quo in the strict sense is not always a
sine qua non for a fee. The element of quid pro quo is not necessarily absent
in every tax. It is enough if there is a broad, reasonable and general corelationship
between the levy and the resultant benefit to the class of people on which the
fee is levied though no single payer of the fee receives direct or personal
benefit from those services. It is immaterial that the general public may also
be benefited from some of the services if the primary service intended is for
the payers of the fees.
(8)Absence
of uniformity is not a criterion on which alone it can be said that the levy is
of the nature of a tax. The legislature has power to enact appropriate
retrospective legislation declaring levies as fees by denuding them of the
characteristics of tax.
(9)It
is not necessary that the amount of fees collected by the Government should be
kept separately. In view of the provisions of Article 266, all amounts received
by the Governments have to be credited to the Consolidated Funds and to the
public accounts of the respective Governments.
22.In
the light of the above law with regard to the levy of fee we have to consider
whether the fee levied by the appellant-Market Committees in the present case
is illegal.
The
impugned decision has relied upon the earlier decision of the same Court to
come to the conclusion that in the absence of any services rendered by the
Market Committees with regard to the transactions of sale and purchase of
bamboos, the respondent-Mills is not liable to pay the market fee. It is,
therefore, necessary to deal with the said earlier decision of the said Court
which was delivered on 12-1-1988 in Miscellaneous Petition No. 4063
of 1986 filed by the respondent-Mills against the State.
23.As
stated at the outset, there is no dispute that bamboo is an agricultural
produce within the meaning of the Act and is a notified agricultural produce
under it. The respondent-Mills purchases and takes delivery of the bamboos from
the forest depots of the Forest Department of the State Government. These
depots are situated within the market area of the appellant-Market Committees.
After taking delivery from the forest depots, the bamboos are transported by
the respondent-Mills to its factory which is also situated within the market
area of one of the committees.
The
services which are rendered by the Market Committees, among others, are as follows:
Covered auction platform and open auction platform, godowns, shops-cum-godowns,
office building, provision of all categories of staff and their training,
office equipment, badges and uniforms for the staff, books, 675 magazines and
advertisement expenses, weighing instruments and weights, security guards,
water coolers, rest house for agriculturists, tubewells and pipelines, overhead
tanks, pump house, mini-sheds and covered-shed and parking area, cattle-shed,
sanitary blocks, light arrangements with all fittings, roads, boundary walls,
check-posts and canteen building.
24.On
behalf of the appellant-Committees, their income and expenditure account for
the five years, viz., 1985-86 to 1989-90 has been annexed to the appeal memo.
As is stated in the memo itself, these details were not filed before the High
Court since the appellants' averments in that behalf in the counter filed in
the High Court, were not denied by the respondent-Mills. As per these details,
the income from market fee recovered and the expenditure incurred for the five
year period 1985-86 to 1989-90 in the case of both the appellant-Committees,
was as follows:
-----
|-----------------------|---------------------------- Years | Income (in Rs) |
Expenditure (in Rs) ------ |---------- |-----------|----------|-----------------
| Appellant1|AppeLlant2 |Appellant1|Appellant 2 ------ |---------- |----------
|----------|--------------- 1985-86| 226518.69 |1711094.71 |166447.15
|851178.73 1986-87| 247248.47 |1856387.98 |254291.20 |1356002.44 1987-88|
244506.43 |3311000.70 |424512.70 |3008839.53 1988-89| 293449.10 |3915838.67
|323202.35 |2715734.74 1989-90| 209403.61 |3731315.34 |322041.70 |3442650.67
-------|-----------|-----------|----------|-------------------- The expenses
are excluding those incurred on capital assets like roads and buildings. These
figures will show that there is a reasonable nexus between the market fees
levied and the expenses incurred on the services rendered to the buyers and
sellers of the agricultural produce.
25. What
is further, the provisions of Section 17 of the Act cast a duty on the market
committee to provide such facilities for marketing of notified agricultural
produce in the market area as the State Government may from time to time direct
and to do such other acts as may be necessary in relation to the
superintendence and control of the market area for regulating the marketing of
notified agricultural produce in any place in the market area and for purposes
connected with the said matters. Among other things, the market committees are
required to
(i) maintain
and manage the market yards;
(iii) provide
the necessary facilities for marketing of agricultural produce in the market
yard;
(iii) grant
or refuse licences to the market functionaries and renew, suspend or cancel
such licences;
(iv) supervise
the conduct of the market functionaries;
(v) regulate
the opening, closing and suspending of trading in the market yards;
(vi) enforce
the conditions of the licences;
(vii) regulate
the making, carrying out and enforcement or cancellation of agreement of sales,
the weighment, delivery, payment and all other matters relating to the
marketing of notified agricultural produce;
(viii)
provide for the settlement of all disputes between the seller and the buyer
arising out of any kind of transaction connected with the marketing of notified
agricultural produce and all matters ancillary thereto;
(ix) collect
and maintain 676 information in respect of production, sale, storage,
processing, prices and movement of notified agricultural produce and
disseminate such information as directed by the Director of Marketing appointed
by the State Government under the Act;
(x) take
all possible steps to prevent adulteration of goods and promote grading and standardisation
of the notified agricultural produce;
(xi)
with a view to maintain stability in the market-(a) take suitable measures to
ensure that traders do not buy agricultural produce beyond their capacity and
avoid risk to the sellers in disposing of the produce; and (b) grant licences
only after obtaining necessary security in cash and bank guarantee according to
the capacity of the buyers;
(xii) levy
and recover all moneys related to fees and other charges due, which the market
committee is authorised to receive;
(xiii)(a)
ensure payment in respect of transaction which takes place in the market yard
or market proper to be made on the same day to the seller, and in default to
seize the agricultural produce in question along with other property of the
person concerned and to arrange for resale thereof and in the event of loss, to
recover the same from the original buyer together with charges for recovery of
loss, if any from the original buyer and effect payment of the price of the
agricultural produce to the seller, (b) recover the charges in respect of weighment
and hammal, and to distribute the same to weighmen and hammals;
(xiv) employ
the necessary number of officers and servants for the efficient implementation
of provisions of the Act, and the rules and the bye-laws made thereunder;
(xv) regulate
the entry of persons and vehicular traffic into the market yard;
(xvi) prosecute
persons for violating the provisions of the Act, and the rules and the bye-laws
made there under and to compound such offences if necessary;
(xvii)
acquire, hold and dispose of any movable or immovable property for the purpose
of efficiently carrying out its duties;
(xviii)
institute or defend any suit, action, proceeding, application or arbitration
and compromise such suit action, proceeding, application or arbitration;
(xix) make
arrangement for employing by rotation, weighmen and hammals for weighing and
transporting of goods in respect of transactions held in the market yard;
(xx) to
provide on rent, storage facilities for stocking of agricultural produce to
agriculturists;
(xxi) arrange
for preventive measures against spread of contagious cattle disease.
26.In
addition, the market committees are required to contribute to the Market
Committee Fund constituted under Section 38 of the Act and the said fund is to
be utilised for the purposes mentioned in Section 39 of the Act. Those
purposes, among others, are
(i) the
acquisition of a site or sites for the market yards;
(ii) the
maintenance and improvement of the market yards;
(iii) the
construction and repairs of buildings, necessary for the purposes of the market
and for convenience or safety of the persons using the market yard;
(iv) the
maintenance of standard weights and measures;
(v) the
meeting of establishment charges including payments and contribution towards
provident fund, pension and gratuity of the officers and servants employed by a
market committee;
(vi)
the payment of interest on the loans that may be raised for the purpose of the
market and provisions of sinking fund in respect of such loans;
(vii) the
collection and dissemination of information relating 677 to crops' statistics
and marketing of agricultural produce;
(viii)(a)
the expenses incurred in auditing the accounts of the market committee;
(b) contribution
to State Marketing Development Fund;
(c) to
develop necessary infrastructure within a radius of one kilometre from the
market yard/sub- market yard for facilitating the flow of notified agricultural
produce.
27.Further,
as pointed out earlier, every market committee is required to pay to the State
Marketing Development Fund, every three months such percentage not exceeding 50
per cent of its gross receipts comprising of licence fees and market fees as
the State Government may by notification declare from time to time. The
Marketing Development Fund is applied under Section 44 of the Act, among
others, for
(i) market
survey and research, grading standardisation of the agricultural produce and
other allied subjects;
(ii) propaganda
and publicity and extension services on the matters, relating to general
improvement of conditions of buying and selling of agricultural produce;
(iii)(a)
giving aid to the market established for the first time in the form of grants
to the extent of fifty thousand rupees to defray the establishment expenses;
(b) giving
aid to financially weak market committees in the scheduled areas of the State
in the form of loans and or grants;
(c)
for loans to any market committee for development of market yard and/or sub-
market yard, construction of cold storage and godown or warehouses;
(iv) acquisition
or constructions or hiring by lease or otherwise of buildings or land for
performing the duties of the Board;
(v)
payment of salary, leave allowance, gratuity, other allowances, loans and
advances and provident fund to the officers and servants employed by the Board
and pension and other contribution to the government servants on deputation;
(vi) better
control of market committees;
(vii) meeting
any legal expenses incurred by the Board;
(viii)
imparting education in regulated marketing of agricultural produce;
(ix)
training the officers and staff of the market committees in the State,
provisions for technical assistance to the market committee in the preparation
of site plans and estimates of construction and in the preparation of project
reports or master plans for development of market yard and
(x) any
other purpose of general interest to regulate marketing of agricultural
produce.
28.It
will be obvious from the above purposes for which the market fee is to be utilised
that the said purposes are in furtherance of the object of the Act, viz., to
regulate the buying and selling of agricultural produce and the establishment
and proper administration of markets for agricultural produce for the benefit
of the agriculturists who are the primary producers of the said produce. The
machinery and the facilities for which the market fees are being expended are
all necessary to provide the necessary infrastructure to further the object of
the Act. But for such infrastructure, the objects of the Act cannot be properly
and adequately implemented. The fact that the respondent-Mills may not be the
direct beneficiary of anyone or some of the said facilities or does not make
use of them does not absolve it from payment of -the market fees. The said
machinery and the facilities are meant for the benefit of all the buyers and
sellers of all the agricultural produce 678 within the market area and it
cannot be denied that they are so. It is further difficult to appreciate the
contention that in the circumstances, the respondent-Mills is not either
directly or indirectly a beneficiary of the said machinery and the facilities
as a buyer of the bamboos when the purchase is admittedly made in the market
area as pointed out above. In the circumstances, the High Court was in error in
holding that there was no evidence of the services rendered by the Committees.
29.In
this connection, a reference may be made to Kewal Krishan Puri case9. There
this Court has upheld the legality of the fees levied for the following
purposes stated in the Punjab Agricultural Produce Markets Act, 1961, viz.,
(i) better
marketing of agricultural produce;
(ii) marketing
of agricultural produce on cooperative lines;
(iii) collection
and dissemination of market rates and news;
(iv) grading
and standardisation of agricultural produce;
(v) general
improvement in the markets;
(vi) maintenance
of the office of the Board and construction and repair of its office buildings,
resthouse and staff quarters;
(vii) giving
aid to financially weak committees in the shape of loans and grants;
(viii)
payment of salary, travel and leave allowance, gratuity, compassionate
allowance, compensation for injuries or death resulting from accidents while on
duty, medical aid, pension or provident fund to the persons employed by the
Board and leave and pension contribution to government servants on deputation;
(ix) travelling
and other allowances to the employees of the Board, its members and members of
Advisory Committees;
(xii) meeting
any legal expenses incurred by the Board;
(xiii)
imparting education in marketing;
(xiv)
construction of godowns;
(xv) loans
and advances to the employees and
(xvi) expenses
incurred in auditing the accounts of the Board. All these purposes are also
covered by the present Act.
30.The
High Court in the present case, accepted the contention of the writ petitioners
before it, i.e., the respondent-Mills herein that so far as the bamboos grown
on private land are concerned, they are to be purchased by the State Government
in view of the provisions contained in the Van Upaj Adhiniyam. Further, the
sale of such bamboos by the Government takes place at various forest depots and
hence the requirement of the Act that the agricultural produce shall be sold in
the market proper or market area does not apply to the present case. This also
applied to bamboos grown on the forest land belonging to the Government. The
contention advanced on behalf of the respondent-State Government there that the
market fee is required to be paid on every agricultural produce brought for
sale or sold in the market area was rejected by the Court on the ground that
the respondent-Mills did not purchase the bamboos for sale but purchased them
for use as its raw material for manufacture of paper. Secondly, there was
nothing in the return filed by the State Government to show that any services
were rendered to the respondent-Mills in return for the market fees levied oil
them for the purchase of bamboos which transaction took place at various forest
depots. The bamboos were purchased by them not for sale but for being used for
manufacture of paper. Although, the Court noted the fact that it is not 679
necessary that each individual trader must be benefited by the services
provided, the Court held that it was necessary to justify the levy by proving
that some direct or indirect benefit was conferred either on the purchasers or
traders of bamboos as a class by the Market Committee. The Court also held that
since the State Government's stand was that the Forest Department would be a
trader within the meaning of the Act while selling bamboos and since
respondent-Mills are also traders according to the State Government, the sale
of bamboos to the respondent by the Forest Department would be a sale by a
trader to a trader and in such a case, the proviso to sub-section (2) of
Section 19 of the Act shall be attracted. That proviso contemplates that in a
case of commercial transaction between traders in the market area, the market
fee shall be collected and paid by the seller.
Hence,
according to the High Court, even if it was accepted for the sake of argument
that market fee on the sale of bamboos by the State Government to the
respondent-Mills was leviable, it was not to be paid to the Market Committee by
the respondent Mills who were the buyers. It was to be collected and paid by
the Forest Department which is the seller. Hence, the Market Committees could
not require the respondent-Mills to pay the market fee directly to them.
31.We
are afraid that on both these counts, the High Court has committed errors. As
regards the first ground on which the High Court has set aside the market fee,
viz., that the transaction of sale and purchase of the bamboos at the forest
depots is not a transaction in the market proper or market yard and hence it is
not prohibited by the Act, the High Court has failed to notice the relevant
provisions of Section 6(b) of the Act to which a reference has already been
made earlier. The provision in terms states that no person shall, except in
accordance with the provisions of the Act and the rules and the bye-laws made thereunder,
use any place in the market area for the marketing of the notified agricultural
produce or operate in the market area as a market functionary. The exceptions
to this provision are mentioned in Section 6(b) itself and the sale of the
bamboos at the forest depots which are admittedly in the market areas of one or
the other committee, are not covered by any of the exceptions. The prohibition
for sale or purchase of the agricultural produce is not only in the market
proper or market yard area but in the market area as a whole. So also Section
31, as already pointed out, further provides that no person shall, in respect
of any notified agricultural produce, operate in the market area as commission
agent, trader, broker, weighman, hammal, surveyor, warehouseman, owner or
occupier of processing or pressing factories or such other market functionary
except in accordance with the provisions of the Act and the rules and bye-laws
made thereunder. Section 37 requires that every person who buys notified
agricultural produce in the market area, shall execute an agreement in favour
of the seller in triplicate in such forms as may be prescribed.
One
copy of such agreement is to be kept in the record of the market committee.
32.As
regards the reliance placed by the High Court on the second proviso to
sub-section (2) of Section 19 of the Act which provides that in case of a
commercial transaction between traders in the market area, the 680 market fee
shall be collected and paid by the seller, we are unable to understand as to
how the said provision can be pressed into service to negative the levy of the
market fee, even assuming that the Forest Department is for the purposes of the
said provision, a trader when it sells the bamboos.
The
Forest Department is required by that provision to collect the fees from the
buyers- in the present case, from the respondent-Mills. The market fee has,
therefore, in any case, to be paid by the respondent-Mills if not to the Market
Committee directly, at least to the Forest Department, and it is to be paid at
the time of the purchase of the bamboos. It is immaterial for this purpose
whether the bamboos are purchased by the respondent-Mills for selling them or
for using them as their raw material in the manufacture of paper. The liability
of the respondent-Mills to pay the market fees is in no way negated on that
account.
The
provision requiring the seller to collect the market fees in such cases is made
for the convenience of collection of the fees, as is the similar provision made
in the first proviso of the said sub-section where buyers cannot be identified.
The collection made by the seller, i.e., the forest depots in the present case
is for and on behalf of the Committee and is eventually to be handed over to
the Committee. The provision is enabling and does not prevent the Committee
itself from collecting the fee, if it so proposes.
33. We
are, therefore, of the view that the High Court was in error in holding that
the levy of market fees in the present case was not legal. The appeal is,
therefore, allowed with costs and the impugned decision of the High Court is
set aside.
Back