Shari Malaprabha Coop. Sugar Factor Vs.
Union of India [1993] INSC 434 (13 October 1993)
MOHAN,
S. (J) MOHAN, S. (J) VENKATACHALLIAH, M.N.(CJ) THOMMEN, T.K. (J) CITATION:
1994 AIR 1311 1994 SCC (1) 648 JT 1993 (6) 561 1993 SCALE (3)927
ACT:
HEADNOTE:
The
Judgment of the Court was delivered by MOHAN, J.- All these cases can be dealt
with under a common judgment since what is under attack is the fixation of
price of levy sugar under orders issued under Section 3(3-C) of the Essential
Commodities Act, 1955 (hereinafter referred to as 'the Act').
2. To
highlight the points in issue we will refer to the facts of the case relating
to the State of Karnataka.
C.A. Nos. 122-23 of 1981 and C.A. Nos. 1253-57 of 1977:
3. In
these appeals two sugar orders are 1975-76 and 1977-78.
4. In
exercise of the powers conferred under Section 3 of the Act, the Central
Government on June 15,
1972 promulgated the
Levy Sugar Supply (Control) Order of 1972 (hereinafter referred to as 'the Levy
Order'). That provides for compulsory supply or sale of sugar from a producer
or a recognised dealer of a specified quantity to a person or Organisation or
to such State Governments as it may direct from time to time. Under the said
Levy Order, the Central Government issues release orders to the producers or
manufacturers against which the manufacturers supply sugar. The Central
Government is required to pay the price. Such a price is determined in
accordance with Section 3(3-C) of the Act. Altogether 5 orders were issued. For
the year 1975-76 the following three orders were issued:
1.
GSR571(E)/Ess.Com/Sugar,datedNovember29,1975
2. GSR
67(E)/Ess. Com/Sugar, dated February 9, 1976
3. GSR 67(E)t/Ess. Com/Sugar, dated August 3, 1976.
5. For
the year 1977-78 the following two orders were issued:
1. GSR
76(E)/Ess. Com/Sugar, dated December 22, 1977
+ Ed.: GSR 749(E) 652
6. The
attack against all these notifications by the manufacturers of sugar 6. The
attack against all these notifications by the manufacturers of sugar in the
writ petitions before the Karnataka High Court was that in price fixation the
Central Government had not taken into consideration the relevant criteria laid
down under Section 3(3-C) of the Act.
7. The
Central Government opposed the stand and urged that the relevant considerations
were borne in mind.
8. The
learned Single Judge struck down all the determinations on the ground of
non-application of mind.
Aggrieved
by this, the matter was taken up in appeal. For the year 1975-76 the Division
Bench was of the view that though the orders dated November 29, 1975 and July II, 1975 could not be upheld insofar as the order
dated February 9, 1976 varied the price by 99 paise more.
That evidenced application of mind and hence could not be struck down.
Concerning
1977-78 the order dated November
29, 1975 had to be
struck down because it was based on an obsolete data of more than 16 months.
During that period, there has been great escalation which ought to have been
taken note of.
With
reference to the notification dated March 1, 1978 the Division Bench was of the view
that the Government had taken into account free sale realisation of the
previous year at the rate of Rs 319 per quintal. During that period, free sale
prices had gone down to distress levels. Therefore, the price fixation was not
in order. Accordingly, the matter was remitted to the Government to consider
afresh and fix proper prices on relevant criteria.
9. On
certificate, both the Government and the manufacturers have come up in appeal.
Various writ petitions questioning the correctness of these notifications have
also been transferred to this Court.
10.
Similarly, in other High Courts the price fixation was questioned. The High
Courts have rendered their decisions.
Insofar
as the sugar producers are concerned they have come up in appeal. Equally, the
Central Government, to the extent it is aggrieved, has preferred appeals.
11.
The arguments of Mr F.S. Nariman, learned counsel, appearing for some of the
sugar producers are as under:
12.
Section 3(3-C) of the Act was specifically enacted to provide for the manner of
fixation of price of sugar in cases where sugar was produced for distribution
by Government. According to the learned counsel the price fixation must be done
on the principles laid down by the Tariff Commission and Sugar Enquiry
Commission mainly on the following bases:
1.
Fair price of cane fixed by Government;
2.
cess or tax payable thereon;
3.
manufacturing cost; and 4. a reasonable return on capital employed.
13. In
support of this submission reliance is placed on Panipat Cooperative Sugar
Mills v. Union of India.
1
(1973) 1 SCC 129: (1973) 2 SCR 860 653
14.
This interpretation is in line with the earlier ruling of Diwan Sugar &
General Mills (P) Ltd. v. Union of India2.
No
doubt, that case dealt with Clause 5 of the Sugar Control Order of 1955. The
words used thereunder were "with due regard to". The factors
mentioned in Clause 5 of the said Sugar Control Order are substantially the
same as under Section 3(3-C) of the Act. The latter ruling construed the words
"having regard to" as factors mentioned in Section 3(3-C) as
essential in price determination.
15.
The further submission of the learned counsel is when Section 3(3- C) of the
Act says 'determination' it cannot be a purported determination. It signifies
an effective expression of opinion which ends a controversy or dispute by some
authority to whom it is submitted under a valid law for disposal. Thus, it is
submitted that the observations in Shri Sitaram Sugar Co. Ltd. v. Union of
India3 are not a fetter, they are not words of limitation but of general
guidance to make an estimate requires fresh consideration.
16. It
is further urged that in the instant cases, it cannot be said there is a valid
determination because the levy price for one year cannot be the levy price for
the subsequent years as indeed the minimum cane price for one year is not the
same for the subsequent years. Similarly, the notification of uniform increase
of Rs 18.03 for each zone for 1977-78 is not correct as it is without reference
to the parameters which are known and calculated for each zone. What had been
done was merely to take a weighted all- India average. This is contrary to the Government's stand of zonal
determination. Though this Court has taken the view that the determination
under Section 3(3-C) is a legislative function, yet a review of subordinate
legislation is permissible on the following grounds:
1. It
is unreasonable.
2. It
is uncertain or repugnant to the general law or some other statute. Support for
this is sought from the case Mixnam's Properties Ltd. v. Chartsey Urban
District Council4.
17.
This Court, it is urged, has also taken the view in Indian Express Newspapers (Bombay) Pvt. Ltd. v. Union of India5 that
a subordinate legislation can be questioned on any ground on which the plenary
legislation could be questioned. According to the ruling, it could be
questioned on the ground that it is unreasonable, unreasonable not in the sense
of not being reasonable but in the sense it is manifestly arbitrary. Viewed in
this light, while fixing the price under Section 3(3-C) regard must be had to
Clause 5A. That provides for an additional minimum price which is statutorily
required to be paid by the manufacturer of sugar to the sugar-cane grower.
Therefore, the grower's share (additional price payable to growers out of the
excess realisation) has necessarily to be included as an element under factor A
or Section 3(3-C). Thus, the minimum price under Section 3(3-C) and the 2 1959
Supp 2 SCR 183 : AIR 1959 SC 626 3 (1990) 3 SCC 223 : (1990) 1 SCR 909 4 (1963)
2 All ER 787: 61 LGR 489 5 (1985) 1 SCC 641 : 1985 SCC (Tax) 121 : (1985) 2 SCR
287 654 additional minimum price under Clause 5-A are essential components of
manufacturing cost of sugar under factor B.
Then
again, mopping up of the entire excess realisation by the sale of free sugar is
incorrect in view of Clause 5-A.
That
would result in total denial of any return resulting in not even recovering the
actual cost of production.
18.
Prior to October 1, 1974 mopping up might have been
permissible. But after October 1, 1974, the mopping up for arriving at a price
under Section 3(3-C) is contrary to law i.e. the law enacted in Clause 5-A
which contemplates excess free market sales realisation for the benefit of
growers to the extent of 50 per cent. The entire theory of "mopping
up" of 100 per cent of extra sale realisation will be contrary to law,
namely, Clause 5-A. This will also be against the recommendations of Bhargava
Commission.
19. Mr
B.R.L. lyengar, learned counsel appearing for the sugar manufacturers of the
State of Karnataka states that till the departure in
the notification dated July II, 1975, the itemisation and the factors of the
format for arriving at the levy price were those repeatedly laid down by the
Tariff Commission. The incidence of additional cane price over and above the
statutorily notified minimum price and the estimated average realisation on the
sale of levy free sugar was at Rs 317.65 for internal consumption and for
exports. The result of inclusion of these items which were not of the standard
formula till then adopted by the Tariff Commission, whether so intended or not,
bring about as far as the Southern and other zones are concerned, the reduction
of the price from Rs 171.52 to Rs 139.72. It is this drastic reduction which is
complained of in these cases.
20. As
can be seen from the report of Bhargava Commission, the object was to reward
efficient factories which pay a fair price to the cane growers but not to give
such a benefit to an inefficient sugar factory. In the case of Panipat Sugar
Mills' which has not been correctly understood, the Court was only ascertaining
that the factories in Haryana got a reasonable return on the capital employed
and for that purpose, took into account excess realisation from the sale of
levy free sugar.
21. Mr
C.S. Vaidyanathan, learned counsel appearing for the sugar mills of Tamil Nadu
submits that Section 3(2)(f) of the Act deals with a situation of acquisition
of immovable property on payment of compensation. This is in contrast to
Section 3(2)(c) of the Act wherein a power is conferred on the Government to
control the prices of essential commodities.
22.
When Section 3(3-C) came up to be introduced containing guidelines for
determination of the price of sugar compulsorily acquired under Section 3(2)(f)
of the Act the Parliament could not have laid down as a guideline that the
Government should take into account as a factor in such price determination,
the additional realisation of non-levy sugar so as to depress the price of levy
sugar even less than the actual cost. While determining the price of levy sugar
the Central Government is bound to take into account the four factors mentioned
in clauses (a) to (d) of Section 3(3-C) of the Act. The Government is bound to
fully compensate the manufacturers of sugar at least 655 under clauses (a) to
(c) as they represent the basic cost.
Even
assuming the Government can ignore the return on the capital in other
construction under Section 3(3-C) would be violative of Articles 14, 19(1)(f),
19(1)(g) and 31(2) of the Constitution of India. The only question that arose
for consideration in Sitaram Mills case3 related to zonewise price fixation.
The price determination in accordance with factors (a) to (d) of Section 3(3-C)
did not call for consideration in that case. It is also not correct to state
that judicial review of price determination is altogether excluded in view of
Sitaram case3.
23.
The Central Government acts on the advice of expert bodies like Tariff
Commission and Bureau of Industrial Costs and Prices while determining the
prices. The specific- case of the Government is that the recommendations of
these bodies have been accepted. If that be so, the additional realisation
should not enter into competition of the price under Section 3(3-C) of the Act.
The additional realisation will have to be shared by the sugar-cane grower and
the sugar producer. Whatever might have been the position of Section 3(3-C) as
construed by this Court in Panipat case1 the same has been deliberately
departed from by the Government by introducing Clause 5-A. As a result, the
additional realisation on free sale sugar cannot be taken into account as a
neutralising factor under clause (d) partially or fully. The contention that
Clause 5-A has no relevance for determination of price under Section 3(3-C) is
untenable.
24. Mr
Raja Ram Agarwal, learned counsel appearing for the sugar factories of East
Uttar Pradesh, in addition to filing the necessary data in detail showing the
break-up of levy prices, urges that according to the Bhargava Commission
Inquiry Report which acceptance is borne out by introduction of Clause 5-A, the
balance of 50 per cent from excess realisation was left with the industry for
certain specific purposes and not for depressing the levy sugar price.
Therefore,
if the free sale realisation is excluded the loss would be even more. The
fixation of levy price for East Zone of Uttar Pradesh is totally arbitrary and
requires to be reconsidered.
25. Mr
S.S. Khanduja, learned counsel adopts the arguments of Mr Raja Ram Agarwal and
prays for redetermination.
26. Mr
Shanti Bhushan, learned counsel for the sugar factories of West Uttar Pradesh
submits that in the decision of Sitaram case3 it has been laid down that the
price fixation under Section 3(3-C) is a legislative power. The very same
decision states that it could be challenged on the following grounds:
(i) If
the fixation of levy price is arbitrary.
(ii)
If it is fixed on extraneous grounds.
(iii)
If it is not done in good faith.
(iv)
If ultra vires of the power granted and not on consideration of relevant
material facts.
(v) If
it is manifestly unjust oppressive or outrageous or directed to an unauthorised
end. 656
(vi)
If it does not tend in some degree to accomplish the objects of delegation.
(vii)
If it is made on irrelevant grounds.
(viii)
Without regard to relevant considerations.
With
reference to these grounds he submits that no data has been disclosed by the
Government to this Court. For four years, 1975-76, 1976-77, 1977-78 and 1978-79
the Government had fixed levy sugar prices without regard to any of the factors
mentioned in clauses (a) to (d) of Section 3(3-C).
In
every sugar year the recovery in a zone varies from year to year to a very great
extent. Therefore, the minimum cane price notified in clause (a) must be by
applying the actual recovery figure. However, for these four years instead of
calculating the minimum cane price on the basis of actual recovery for the zone
in the previous year what has been taken into consideration is an identical
recovery, namely, 9.65 per cent. Therefore, clause (a) is violated.
27.
Then again, the cost of conversion mentioned under clause (b) depends on the
duration of the sugar season and the recovery from sugarcane. These factors are
bound to vary. For all these four years, the Government has assumed an
identical duration of 139 days in West U.P. Zone. Hence, there is disregard of
clause (b).
28. If
price determination is to be done with reference to clauses (a), (b), (c) and
(d) these factors are always different in different years. It is not possible
for the levy sugar price to be the same for any zone for two successive years.
For the year 1975-76 the notification dated August 3, 1976 fixed the price at Rs 163.79. By
notification dated November
19, 1976 for the year
1976-77 the levy sugar price was fixed at Rs 163.79. Again, notification dated December 22, 1977 fixed the levy sugar price at Rs
163.79 for 1977-78. These notifications per se are not in conformity with the
factors mentioned in clauses (a) to (d) of Section 3(3-C). Then again, where
the Government is required to revise the price with reference to each zone a
uniform increase of Rs 18.03 per quintal over the price fixed under the notification
dated November 22, 1979 for all the zones, is not
contemplated at all.
29.
The realisation from free sale sugar to depress the levy sugar price is
illegal. That is against the report of the Tariff Commission and also
disregards Clause 5-A which is based on Bhargava Commission Report accepted by
the Government. The respondent has recommended that the excess realisation from
sale should be shared by the factories on 50:50 basis with the cane growers and
necessary steps were being taken from the ensuing sugar season. The loss
sustained by sugar factory on its export quota is not taken into consideration.
This is also bad in law.
30.
Even assuming that the extra realisation from free sugar could be used for
decreasing the amount of return which may be provided under clause (d) the
sugar factories would at least be entitled to a price determination in
accordance with the factors mentioned under clauses (a), (b) and (c) of Section
3(3-C). That is not so in the present case. For the years 657 1978-79 and 1979-80
the sugar factories paid to the sugar growers only the statutory minimum cane
price. It was that statutory minimum cane price that has been taken into
consideration. At the same time, the extra realisation from free sugar went
into calculation. This resulted in depressing the levy price and mopping up of
the extra free sugar realisation for calculating the levy price. This is
opposed to Clause 5-A.
31.
Taking into consideration the extra realisation by the sale of free sugar it is
not in accordance with the view expressed by the Court in Panipat Sugar Mills
case 1.
32. If
the price fixation does not result in a reasonable return not even providing
for the cost of cane and the cost of conversion, the price fixation is liable
to be struck down where the Government is obliged to fix the price on the L
Factor. It has to be so fixed in respect of the entire levy sugar production.
Therefore, even for a provisional price fixed during the beginning of the
season, at the end of the season it has to be revised.
33. Mr
B. Sen, learned counsel after referring to (a) Panipat Sugar Mills v. Union of
India'; (b) Anakapalle Cooperative Agrl. & Industrial Society Ltd. v. Union
of India6 and (c) Shri Sitaram Sugar Co. Ltd. v. Union of India3 points out
that the price fixation is vitiated as it has been based on considerations
which are not germane.
Firstly,
price fixation has been done on the basis of estimates in relation to factors
contained in clauses (a) to (d) of Section 3(3-C). Thereafter some additions
and deductions have been made from the figure arrived at on the basis of
estimates. The addition is on the actual cane price payable while the deduction
is based on the estimate realisation from sale of free sugar. The realisation
from sale of free sugar is not germane except for purpose of clause (d). The
factors mentioned in clauses (a), (b) and (c) are those based on weighted
average cost involved in relation to each item.
34.
The fixation of price based on estimates on the beginning of the season and not
updating has caused the industry to suffer loss. For example, for the year
1979-80 the levy price fixed at the beginning of the season was Rs 250.45 while
L Factor worked out to Rs 294.07.
35. Mr
H.J. Javeri, learned counsel appearing for the cooperative society situated in
Saurashtra region submits that Panipat' and Anakapalle6 rulings upheld price
determination by Government of India since such determination was based on the
recommendations of the Tariff Commission fixing the prices for different zones
by adopting the method of working out the weighted averages. Such a method of
price fixation would not now be relevant particularly when a better method of
pricing of sugar by an expert body such as Bureau of Industrial Costs and
Pricing is available.
36.
Though in Sitaram case3 the Court refused to reopen the earlier decisions it
was on the ground that no material was brought to the notice of the Court to
establish that the Central Government had not applied its mind to the price
fixation. However, that decision does lay down that the price 6 (1973) 3 SCC
435 :(1973) 2 SCR 882 658 fixation could be challenged on the ground of
unreasonableness or arbitrariness. Insofar as the entire State of Gujarat was
placed in a zone along with Maharashtra and Goa without regard to the relevant
conditions of yield recovery and availability of sugar-cane as they materially
differ, the price fixation must be held to be arbitrary.
Even
in Gujarat there are two zones. The units in Saurashtra are to be placed in low
recovery zones while those in South Gujarat are to be grouped in high recovery
zones. Further, the capital cost of establishment of these units also
materially differ. The High Court of Gujarat failed to appreciate this
important aspect of the matter.
In
actualities, the cane growers were paid a higher price than the statutory
minimum price. This is because the appellant-society had to pay harvesting and
transport charges. This important factor ought to have been taken note of by
the Government.
37. Mr
P.V. Kapur, learned counsel appearing for the sugar mills of Haryana would urge
that in respect of the year 1977-78 the Central Government issued an order
dated December 22, 1977. By that order it had mechanically and without
application of mind repeated the price fixed earlier for the season 1976-77 in
utter disregard of cost escalation. The higher sugar price and purchase tax on
cane which was increased by the State Government from Rs 13 to Rs 13.50 and
from Rs 1.25 to Rs 1.50 per quintal respectively and higher labour cost and
other relevant factors like expected recovery and duration which had to be
taken into account.
38. Mr
Altaf Ahmed, learned Additional Solicitor General on behalf of the Union of
India after drawing our attention to the various provisions of the Essential
Commodities Act, 1955
submits that sub-section (3-C) of Section 3 is a link in a statutory chain
consisting of sub-section (2)(f), sub- section (1) of Section 3 and the
preamble of the Act. The object of the Act is to aim at equitable distribution
of sugar at fair prices. Clause 5-A of the Sugar-cane Control Order would form
a part of that scheme by virtue of clause (d) of sub-section (3-C). The effect
of the argument that Section 3(3C) is not consumer-oriented but producer-
oriented, designed with the object of protecting the producer's profit and does
not permit price control would amount to tearing it out of statutory context.
39.
'Reasonable return' may be a term of art. It is for this reason the return
recommended by the Tariff Commission is totally protected against the impact of
Clause 5-A. The High Court of Madras has confused the underlying purpose of
sub-section (3-C) with the concept of providing compensation for compulsory acquisition
of property underlying Article 31(2) of the Constitution. Essential Commodities
Act is not made under Entry 42 of List III of Seventh Schedule but under Entry
33 of List III. In any event, Article 31 stands deleted by virtue of
Constitution (Forty-fourth Amendment) Act, 1978. Therefore, to hold that
sub-section (3-C) is only for partial control of sugar is incorrect. This
finding overlooks that sub-section (3-C) refers to sub- section (2)(f) under
which an order can be made both for partial or complete control.
659
40.
The finding that Section 3(3-C) did not enable the Government to effect price
control of sugar but will merely enable it to fix levy price of sugar is
incorrect. The judgment of the Karnataka High Court rendered by a learned Single
Judge holding that Clause 5-A supersedes Section 3(3- C) is apposite to the
ruling of this Court in Panipat case'.
He
would commend for our acceptance the view taken by the Allahabad High Court.
41. In
opposing the stand of Mr Nariman, learned counsel, it is urged that Clause 5-A
of Sugar-cane Control Order provides for payment of additional cane price. Such
payment would arise only in case of surplus from sales of both levy and free
sugar after adjustment of the unit cost of production. This surplus may or may
not arise. Therefore, it is, by no means, a mandatory payment like minimum
bonus.
The L
Factor refers to the sale value of the entire production and not merely the
sale of free sugar.
42. It
is not correct to state that bonus creditor interest on borrowed capital and
debentures were not taken into account in the determination of levy sugar price
for 1974-75 and 1975-76. In fact, the cost schedules recommended by the Tariff
Commission in its Report of 1973 did mention these factors which are accepted
by the Government with suitable adjustment.
43. It
is not a fact that a reasonable return was not provided by the Government. The
price of levy sugar fixed for a zone is intended to ensure to the manufacturers
a reasonable return on their overall production and investment provided the
units are run economically and effectively. It is not contemplated that the
price should protect the imprudent extravagant or mismanaged factories. In
other words, the Government does not act as an insurer.
44. In
cases arising in East U.P. the conclusion drawn by the appellants is that
all-India average is taken into account. In the affidavit of the Government the
impact of raising free sale percentage from 13 to 35 on sugar industry, as a
whole, has been indicated. This does not relate to East Uttar Pradesh alone.
45.
The levy is fixed with reference to a zone, as a whole.
Therefore,
the impact of such a fixation on individual factory is irrelevant. In Sitaram
case3 this Court has upheld fixation of levy sugar prices on zonal basis.
46.
The sugar factory pays price for the cane more than the minimum price. This is
higher than the minimum and additional cane price provided under Clause 5-A.
If, therefore, no further payments are liable to be made by the manufacturers
of sugar the entire surplus would be available to the sugar mills besides the
minimum return which is included in L Factor.
47. As
regards cases arising from Maharashtra it is incorrect to state that the
factors mentioned in clauses (a) to (d) of Section 3(3-C) were not home in
mind. In view of the decision of this Court in SitaraM3 not only those factors
but other factors, which have a bearing, were also taken into consideration.
When the appellants talk of reasonable return it should be noted that reasonable
return refers to the entire production of sugar, That 660 would be sufficient
compliance with law as laid down in Panipat case'. Under Clause 5-A of the
Sugar-cane Control Order sugar producer is required to pay to the sugar-cane
growers in addition to the minimum sugarcane price fixed under Clause 3(a), an
additional price if found due in accordance with Second Schedule to that order.
This surplus is calculated in terms of Bhargava Commission formula. The
obligation to pay the cane growers arises only if the statutory minimum cane
price plus the surplus exceeds the actual cane price already paid to the
grower. Therefore, only to the extent of excess the payment is required to be
made.
48.
For sugar year 1978-79 the minimum notified prices of sugar-cane have been
considerably increased. Therefore, the appellants cannot have any valid
complaint. The general trend of argument that the actual cane prices were not
taken in Maharashtra for fixation of price for 1978-79 and 1979-80 is
untenable. The Government has not discriminated against Maharashtra. Minimum
cane prices had been adopted in all zones for price determination in these two
years. Free sale prices were adopted where estimates based on data given by the
sugar factories may not correspond with the actuals.
Claim
of actuals of industry has not been backed by proper calculations. The figures
were found to be not supported by documents.
49.
Opposing the stand of Tamil Nadu sugar mills owners it is submitted that the
additional sugar-cane price under Clause 5-A has necessarily to be included as
an element under Section 3(3-C) is based on an incorrect notion. What is termed
as an additional cane price under Clause 5-A is actually the sugar-cane
grower's share of surplus. It cannot be deemed as a sort of a dividend. It can
hardly be considered as an item of cost of production. Since the payment of
additional sugar-cane price would arise only in case profits are available for
sharing between the factories and sugar-cane growers and since the exact
quantum of additional cane price would become known only after the end of the
sugar season, it cannot be taken into account as an element of cost of
production at the time of determination of levy sugar price. The additional
sugar-cane price is not susceptible of quantification at the beginning of the
sugar year.
50.
The objectives of these two provisions, namely, Clause 5-A of the Sugar-cane
Control Order and Section 3(3-C) are different. Even if there is a conflict
between the two, Clause 5-A is subordinate legislation. That cannot supersede
Section 3(3-C). The factors mentioned in clauses (a) to (d) of Section 3(3-C)
are not mandatory in nature since the language used is "having regard
to". Only when the factories obliged to pay additional price, this formula
under Clause 5-A could be worked out. Since the sugar factories were expected
to pay only the minimum notified price the same was considered in working out
the return.
Additional
cane price was never reckoned for consideration as it was payable only in the
case of surplus for sharing between the sugar mills and the sugar-cane growers.
51.
Here, actual cane prices were considered for determining the fair cost of
production. The sugar factories Were entitled to surplus. In such a case, the
grower has been paid not only the statutory minimum price but also 661
additional cane price. Provisions of Clause 5-A come into operation only after
levy price is fixed which is part of Factor R., Therefore, reckoning of extra
free sales realisation in levy price determination cannot be said to be
contrary to Clause 5-A. The same is the position with reference to Karnataka
also. Thus it is prayed that the appeals filed by the Union of India may be
allowed and those of the manufacturer may be dismissed.
52. In
reply to these contentions Mr P.H. Parekh, learned counsel would urge that the
Government should have fixed the prices with reference to the actuals of the
previous year which had not been done. If that had been done the levy prices
would have been higher even under the methodology under challenge. The assumed
free market prices taken for calculation when actuals were available would make
the whole exercise ex facie arbitrary. The importance of this glaring and
patent error would be apparent from the fact that roughly every rupee of free
sale realisation which is assumed as higher would lead to a reduced levy price
to the extent of 50 paise per quintal.
53.
The Union of India has not substantiated why there is mechanical repetition of
the levy prices fixed for earlier season.
54.
Even with regard to Clause 5-A the contention of the Government of India cannot
be accepted. In the Second Schedule of Sugar-cane Control Order which contains
Factor 2 in the denominator representing the fraction 1/2 (50 per cent) of the
excess realisation on sale of sugar. Even according to the Government of India
the growers are entitled not only to the statutory minimum price but also
additional price. The growers must have 50 per cent of the profit.
55.
The Tariff Commission has specifically stated that some of the items of
manufacturing costs were left out of the conversion cost schedule since they
could be adequately met from the additional realisation from sale of free
sugar.
That
being so, this factor ought to have been taken into consideration. Then again,
Bhargava Commission has recommended 50 per cent to the industry for meeting its
commitment for bonus, gratuity and interest on borrowed capital and the
requirements for rehabilitation, modemisation and expansion. These have Dot
been considered at all.
56. In
order to appreciate these points we will first refer to the relevant provisions
of the Essential Commodities Act.
57.
The object and the intendment of the Essential Commodities Act is to secure
equitable distribution and availability of fair prices of essential
commodities. In order to fulfil that object Section 3 authorises the Central
Government to pass orders which may provide for regulating or prohibiting the
production, supply and distribution of an essential commodity and trade and
commerce therein.
58.
Section 3 sub-section (2) clause (f) provides- "(f) for requiring any
person holding in stock, or engaged in the production, or in the business of
buying or selling, of any essential commodity,- 662 (a) to sell the whole or a
specified part of the quantity held in stock or produced or received by him, or
(b) in the case of any such commodity which is likely to be produced or
received by him, to sell the whole or a specified part of such commodity when
produced or received by him, to the Central Government or a State Government or
to an officer or agent of such Government or to a Corporation owned or
controlled by such Government or to such other person or class of persons and
in such circumstances as may be specified in the order." (Explanations
omitted)
59.
The order under Section 3(2)(f) is quasi-judicial in character. It is a
specific order directed to a particular individual in order to enable the
Central Government to purchase a certain quantity of commodity from the person
holding it. It is an order of compulsory sale. When a compulsory sale is
required to be made the question would naturally arise; what is the price to be
paid for that commodity?
60.
Section 3(3-C) provides for the ascertainment of such a price. This has been so
held in Union of India v. Cynamide India Ltd.7
61.
This is how with reference to sugar it has been declared as an essential
commodity the price fixation under Section 3(3-C) comes into play. The said
section provides:
In
calculating the amount to be paid for the commodity required to be sold, regard
is to be had to the following:
(a)
the minimum price, if any, fixed for sugar-cane by the Central Government under
this section;
(b)
the manufacturing cost of sugar;
(c)
the duty or tax, if any, paid or payable thereon; and (d) the securing of a
reasonable return on the capital employed in the business of manufacturing
sugar.
62. It
is further prescribed that different prices may be determined, from time to
time, for different years for different factories or for different kinds of
sugar.
63.
With reference to price fixation following principles emerge from three
important decisions:
(1)
Panipat Sugar Mills v. Union of India'.
(2)
Anakapalle Cooperative Society v. Union of India6.
(3)
Shri Sitaram Sugar Company Ltd. v. Union of India3.
64.
The principles are:
(a)
The amount payable for levy sugar shall be calculated with reference to price
of sugar as the Central Government may determine having regard to four factors
set out in clauses (a), (b), (c) and (d) of Section 3(3-C).
7
(1987) 2 SCC 720 663
65. In
Panipat case' it was observed thus: (SCC p. 139, para 22 : SCR p. 870)
"Sub-section (3-C), with which we are presently concerned, was inserted in
Section 3 by Section 3 of Act 36 of 1967. The sub- section lays down two
conditions which must exist before it applies. The first is that there must be
an order made with reference to sub-section (2), clause (f), and the second is
that there is no notification under sub- section (3-A) or if any such notification
has been issued it is no longer in force owing to efflux of time. Next, the
words 'notwithstanding anything contained in sub- section (3)' suggest that the
amount payable to the person required to sell his stock of sugar would be with
reference to the price fixed under the sub-section and not the agreed price or
the market price in the absence of any controlled price under sub-section
(3-A).
The
subsection then lays down two things;
firstly,
that where a producer is required by an order with reference to sub-section
(2)(f) to sell any kind of sugar, there shall be paid to that producer an
amount therefor, that is for such stock of sugar as is required to be sold, and
secondly, that such amount shall be calculated with reference to such price of
sugar as the Central Government may, by order, determine, having regard to the
four factors set out in clauses (a), (b), (c) and (d).
Unlike
the preceding three sub-sections under which the amount payable is either the
agreed price, or the controlled price, or where neither of these prices is
applicable at the market or average market price, the amount in respect of
sugar required to be sold is to be calculated at the price determined by the
Central Government. The last words of the sub-section empower the Central
Government to determine price either from time to time or for different areas,
which means that it may determine zonal or regional prices, or for different
factories, i.e., unit-wise, or for different kinds of grades of sugar." It
was further observed thus: (SCC p. 140, para 23 : SCR p.
87 1)
"... The words 'such price of sugar', relate to the price which the
Central Government has to determine having regard to clauses (a), (b), (c) and
(d)."
66.
The same is reiterated in Sitaram case3: (SCC p. 241, para 25 : SCR pp. 931-32)
"The price of sugar must be determined by the Central Government having
regard to the factors mentioned in clauses (a) to (d) of subsection (3-C). This
is done with reference to the industry as a whole and not with reference to any
individual seller. In contradistinction to the 'price of sugar', the 'amount'
is calculated with reference to the particular seller. The Central Government
is authorised to determine different prices for different areas or for
different factories or for different kinds of sugar." 664 (b) A fair price
has to be determined. For this purpose, the realisation from sale of free sugar
can be taken into consideration in fixing the rate of return.
67. In
the case of Panipat' it was observed thus: (SCC pp. 140-41, para 25: SCR p.
872) "The fair price, therefore, has to be determined on the minimum price
of cane fixed by Government, the manufacturing cost on the basis of zonal
cost-schedules, the tax or duty applicable in the zones and must be so structured
as to leave in the ultimate result to the industry a reasonable return on the
capital employed by it in the business of manufacturing sugar." (c) The
Government cannot fix an arbitrary price nor can a price be fixed on extraneous
considerations. If such a price does not secure a reasonable return on the
capital employed, such a fixation is liable to be challenged both on the ground
of its being inconsistent with the guidelines built in this subsection and also
as violative of Articles 19(1)(f), 19(1)(g) and 31 of the Constitution.
In the
case of Panipat' it was held thus: (SCC p. 143, para 30) "We are,
therefore, satisfied both on the language of the sub-section, the background in
which it was enacted and the mischief the legislature sought to remedy through
its working that the true construction is that a fair price has to be
determined in respect of the entire produce, ensuring to the industry a
reasonable return on the capital employed in the business of manufacturing
sugar." 68. In Sitaram case3 it was observed thus:
(SCC
p. 25 1, para 45 : SCR p. 943) "Price fixation is in the nature of a
legislative action even when it is based on objective criteria founded on
relevant material. No rule of natural justice is applicable to any such order.
It is nevertheless imperative that the action of the authority should be
inspired by reason.8 The Government cannot fix any arbitrary price. It cannot
fix prices on extraneous considerations.9" (d) It could be held that there
is sufficient compliance with Section 3(3- C) if the Government had applied its
mind to the factors mentioned in clauses (a) to (d) of the said sub-section.
What is essential is, the Government must apply its mind which is relevant to
the determination of prices with due regard to the norms laid down in the said
sub-section.
69. In
Sitaram case3 it was further held thus: (SCC p. 245, para 30: SCR p. 936)
" The reasonableness of the order made by the Government in exercise of
its power under sub-section (3-C) will, of course, be tested by 8 Saraswati Industrial
Syndicate Ltd. v. Union of India, (1974) 2 SCC 630 : (1975) 1 SCR 956, 961, 962
9 State of U.P.v.Renu sagar Power Co.,(1988) 4 SCC 59 665 asking the question
whether or not the matters mentioned in clauses (a) to (d) have been generally
considered by the Government in making its estimate of the price, but the Court
will not strictly scrutinise the extent to which those matters or any other
matters have been taken into account.
There
is sufficient compliance with the sub-section, if the Government has addressed
its mind to the factors mentioned in clauses (a) to (d), amongst other factors
which the Government may reasonably consider to be relevant and has come to a
conclusion, which any reasonable person, placed in the position of the
Government, would have come to." (e) Price fixation is in the nature of a
legislative action, even though it may be based on an objective criteria. It is
nevertheless imperative that the action of the authority should be inspired by
reason. The individual orders calculating the amounts payable to individual
producers are in the nature of administrative orders founded on the mechanics
of price fixation.
70. In
Sitaram case3 it was held: (SCC p. 25 1, para 44:
SCR p.
943) "The individual orders, calculating the 'amounts' payable to the
individual producers, being administrative orders founded on the mechanics of
price fixation, they must be left to the better-instructed judgment of the
executive, and in regard to them the principle of audi alteram partem is not
applicable. All that is required is reasonableness and fairplay which are in
essence emanations from the doctrine of natural justice as explained by this
Court in A.K. Kraipak v. Union of India
10.
" (f) The price fixation on a zonal basis taking into account the average
zonal cost is valid.
71. In
Anakapalle Coop. Society6 it was held thus: (SCC p.
450,
para 27) "Once it is recognised that prices could be fixed according to
the zones the cost schedules that have been worked out by the Commission have
necessarily to be different for each zone. The various items which go into cost
differ from zone to zone. It is not possible to take out only a few items and
find discrimination, disregarding all the other items or components of costs on
the basis of which price determination has to be made. We are unable to hold
that while classifying zones or geographical-cum-agro-economic consideration,
any discrimination was made or that the price fixation according to each zone
taking into account all the relevant factors would give rise to such
discrimination as would attract Article 14 of the Constitution."
72. To
the similar effect are the observations in Sitaram case3: (SCC p. 235, para 11
: SCR pp. 924 and 925) "[T]here is ample justification in continuing and
sustaining the zonal system for the purpose of price fixation. Price has to be
fixed for each zone and necessarily it varies from zone to zone. There is no 10
(1969) 2 SCC 262: (1970) 1 SCR 457 666 discrimination in the classification of
zones on a geographical-cum-agroeconomic consideration and any such
classification is perfectly consistent with the principle of equality."
73.
This Court in Sitaram case3 observed thus: (SCC p. 25 1, para 46) "Any
arbitrary action, whether in the nature of a legislative or administrative or
quasi-judicial exercise of power, is liable to attract the prohibition of
Article 14 of the Constitution."
74. It
is in the light of these principles we propose to examine the correctness of
price fixation by the various orders which are impugned in these cases.
75.
The main thrust of the argument on behalf of the appellants is that price
fixation has proceeded on notional basis without regard to the actualities.
More than above this, clause (d) of sub-section (3-C) ensures a reasonable
return on the capital employed in the business of manufacturing sugar.
Therefore, clause (d) cannot be invoked to limit or restrict the return or to
mop off the profits which the sugar producer may get by sale of free sugar by
fixing a low price for the levy sugar. If really, the price fixation is for the
sale of sugar in Section 3(2)(f) the fair price must be fixed. Further, the
impugned orders are in conflict with Sugar-cane Control Order, particularly
Clause 5-A.
76. In
opposition to this, the Government would urge that there is a valid
determination of the price and not a mere purported determination. The
Government did have regard to clauses (a) to (d) of Section 3(3-C) and fixed
the price for levy sugar taking into account the actual cane price paid and the
excess realisation from free market sales which are relevant criteria.
77. It
cannot be gainsaid that for fixing the price under Section 3(3-C) the
Government must have regard to the four factors mentioned under Section 3(3-C)
of the Act. Those factors are:
(1)
Minimum price of sugar-cane;
(2)
manufacturing costs;
(3)
taxes and duties; and (4) reasonable return on the capital employed.
78. In
Sitaram case3 this Court has categorically laid down that the price fixation is
a legislative function. If that be so, what is permissible for the Court to
examine is whether regard has been had to these four factors and any other
relevant factor. For the 1974-75 season the price determination was fixed under
the following orders:
1.
Price Determination Order No. GSR 670(E)/Ess. Com/Sugar, dated November 28,
1974.
2.
Price Determination Order No. GSR 403(E)/Ess. Com/Sugar, dated July 11, 1975.
79.
The fixation of levy sugar price involves an elaborate exercise such as
forecasting the cane availability, sugar production, duration, recovery etc.
Pending finalisation of all this, the prices notified for 1973-74 were repeated
667 in the first of these two notifications (dated November 28, 1974) as an
interim measure. It had to be so done because the Government had to release
1974-75 sugar season production. Without such a price fixation sugar could not
have been released. This would have resulted in disruption of sugar through
public distribution system.
80. In
January 1975 the Government increased the free sale quota from 30 to 35 per
cent. However, a decision was taken not to review the price immediately as the
increase in free sale quota could have given some relief to the industry by way
of higher realisation. By July 1975 the final working results of the season
were available for almost all the zones. The free sale prices were high
compared to levy sugar prices. Therefore, the Government was required to
determine prices in a suitable manner. The Government having regard to Section
3(3-C) had taken into consideration the following aspects:
(i)
Consideration of minimum price of cane as fixed by Government:
In
fixing that minimum price the Government took into account the statutory
minimum price (SMP) fixed under Section 3(1) of the Sugarcane (Control) Order,
1966 dated July 16, 1966. In addition to this factor, the difference of actual
cane price that would be paid by sugar producers over and above the statutory
minimum cane price was also taken into account. So much so, the Government took
a higher figure than what they were required to do. Thus, compensating the
sugar factories for higher cane price the levy price was determined and
notified.
(ii)
Manufacturing cost of sugar:
The
conversion cost of sugar for all the zones adopting as the basis the Schedules
in this regard recommended by Tariff Commission in their 1973 Report, was duly
adjusted for further escalations.
(iii)
Duties and taxes thereon:
The
Government adjusted the difference between the cost of production including
reasonable return of the, entire sugar and the total realisations from the sale
of levy sugar and fixed levy sugar prices, thereby ensuring a reasonable return
to the producer on the entire production.
Various
Annexures show the break-up of levy sugar price notified in respect of the
zones of Uttar Pradesh, North Bihar, Maharashtra, Goa, Karnataka, Andhra
Pradesh, Tamil Nadu.
81.
Since these aspects have been borne in mind we are unable to hold that the
notional figures had been adopted.
82.
For 1975-76 season there are three notifications:
1.
Levy Sugar Price notified, vide the Government of India Gazette Notification
No.
GSR
571(E)/Ess. Com/Sugar, dated November 29, 1975. 668
2.
Levy Sugar Price notified, vide the Government of India Gazette Notification
No.
GSR
67(E)/ Ess. Com/Sugar, dated February 9, 1976.
3.
Levy Sugar Price notified, vide the Government of India Gazette Notification
No.
GSR
748(E)/Ess. Com/Sugar, dated August 3, 1976.
83.
Pending the finalisation of the levy sugar prices for 1975-76 sugar season, for
which a detailed exercise involving estimates of the availability of cane,
sugar production, duration of the crushing season, recovery, percentage etc.
had to be undertaken by the Government, the prices applicable for 1974-75
season w.e.f. July 12, 1975 were renotified for 197576 sugar season, as an
interim measure. This was done in view of the overriding need to release sugar
stocks out of 1975-76 production for meeting requirements of the public
distribution system.
84.
The renotification of the prices for 1975-76 season w.e.f. November 29, 1975 at
the same level as those in previous season w.e.f. November 29, 1975 cannot be
faulted on grounds of arbitrary exercise of power by the Government for the
following reasons:
(a)
The issuance of the price notification dated November 29, 1975 was intended to
be an interim measure and was a conscious decision to meet the exigencies of
the situation. But, for the timely fixation of the prices, the country would
have faced a serious disruption of the public distribution system in respect of
the supplies of an essential commodity viz., sugar.
(b) An
across-the-board upward or downward revision of the prices pending a detailed
examination of the cost estimates relating to price determination, was hardly
likely to have achieved the real purpose of determination of the levy price.
(c)
The levy sugar price notified on November 29, 1975 was intended to be an
interim measure to be followed soon by the determination of the price after a
more detailed examination of available information and data. The Government had
accordingly decided to set for themselves an urgent time frame for completion
of the price determination exercise.
85.
After an intensive examination of the data on the crucial determinants of the
ex-factory price of levy sugar, the Government notified the levy sugar prices
for 1975-76 season on February 9, 1976.
86.
Thereafter the Government adopted the same methodology of taking into
consideration the factors as were made applicable to 1974-75 season. Levy Sugar
Price for 1976- 77 Sugar Season:
87.
The report of the Bhargava Inquiry Commission was submitted to the Government
on November 8, 1976. In its report the Commission made several recommendations
which made a complete departure from the earlier methodology followed by the
Tariff Commission for decades. The 669 recommendations included grouping of
sugar producing units on similarities of performance characteristic instead of
on a geographical basis. In view of Bhargava Inquiry Commission's emphasis on
treatment of all its recommendations in the report including the above
mentioned recommendations as one single package, it was not found possible to
accept and give effect to any one single recommendation. Because of the
impracticability of implementation of Bhargava Inquiry Commission's main
recommendations, the Government had no other alternative but to repeat 1975-76
prices for 1976-77 sugar season. 1977-78 Season:
88.
For the abovesaid season there are two orders:
(1)
Price Determination Order No. GSR 767(E)/Ess. Com/Sugar, dated December 22,
1977.
(2)
Price Determination Order No. GSR 355(E)/Ess. Com/Sugar, dated March 1, 1978.
At the
beginning of season the Government repeated the prices for 1976-77 season on
December 22, 1977 which was an interim measure only. Many factors such as
estimates of quantity of sugar-cane crushable by sugar factories, anticipated
recovery and duration, estimates of sugar production had to be called for from
the factories for assessing likely working conditions that would prevail in
1977-78 season to enable determination of the levy sugar prices. This was
likely to take quite some time. Since the old price had been continuing for
long time, with the available records the Government estimated all India
average ex-factory price and this was found to be Rs 18.03 more than the
average all India levy sugar prices, as was announced on January 22, 1977. This
increase was uniformly added to prices of all the zones earlier notified on
December 22, 1977 and the new prices that were thus arrived at, were notified
on March 1, 1978. Final levy sugar price was to be determined after crushing
was over. But, by then, decision was taken to decontrol the sugar, which became
effective from August 16, 1978 and levy sugar price was no longer needed.
1978-79 Season:
Price
Determination Order No. GSR 699(E)/Ess. Com/Sugar, dated December 17, 1979.
89.
All controls on production, distribution, movement and prices of sugar were
removed on August 16, 1978 and the Government reintroduced the policy of
partial control w.e.f.
December
17, 1979. Bulk of the production of 1978-79 season was sold when there was no
control on sugar i.e. the sugar mills were free to sell the sugar at the best
price available in the market. With the introduction of partial control, only
65 per cent of the small quantities that remained unsold on December 17, 1979
were declared as 'levy sugar'. The Government had information that the sugar
factories had paid only the minimum cane price notified during the 1978-79
season. The levy sugar prices were determined as per the provision of Section
3(3-C) of the Act viz., taking into account the factors (a) to (d) mentioned
therein. The 670 final levy sugar prices were determined after adjusting the
excess of free sale realisation over the cost of production assessed, so as to
ensure that the industry got a reasonable return on the entire production of
sugar.
90. In
the case of Eastern Uttar Pradesh the following requires to be mentioned.
91.
The Government worked out the levy price assuming recovery and duration but the
actual working results were lower than the assumptions made by the Government.
This was because the Government assumed a certain degree of efficiency. In East
U.P. Zone, it appears that the factories have not been efficient. Certainly, the
Government cannot be expected to reward inefficiency for a higher price. This
zone is a high cost zone. The machinery in the factories is old with poor
working. The Government wanted to provide a reasonable return of Rs 12.80, the
said zone could not earn. On the contrary, it could earn a return of only Rs
7.70. Therefore, to contend that the Government had fixed the price without
regard to the reasonable return is not correct.
92. In
the State of Maharashtra initially an ex-field advance is fixed uniformly for
all cooperative sugar factories. At the end of the season, the actual working
results are assessed and the entire profits are passed on to the cane growers
as additional cane prices. Thus, the farmers get profits in the form of
additional cane prices and this fluctuates widely from factory to factory. In
view of this it can be categorically stated that actual cane prices are not
available in Maharashtra, particularly for cooperative (sic) as it is of a
profit sharing nature (excess over the initial ex-field advance).
93.
Therefore, it is not correct on the part of the appellants to contend that
notional prices were taken into consideration without regard to the
actualities. Even otherwise, as stated above, if regard has been had to this
factor that would be sufficient in law. We may add that this Court cannot
determine the price by redoing that exercise.
94.
With this, we move to the next contention. Mr Nariman, learned counsel urges
that whatever might have been the position when Panipat case was decided,
namely before October 1, 1974, after that date regard must be had to Clause 5-A
of the Sugar-cane Control Order, 1966. After incorporation of the said clause
the Government could not, in law, proceed to determine the levy price by
mopping up 100 per cent of the excess realisation on Sale of free sugar. In the
notifications issued for the sugar years 1974-75 to 1979-80 the Government had
admitted mopping up 100 per cent excess realisation on sale of free sugar. This
clearly overlooks the fact that the producer had become statutorily entitled to
50 per cent of such excess realisation from October 1, 1974.
95.
The changed methodology adopted from July 11, 1975 was directly contrary to the
recommendation of the Sugar Industry Inquiry Commission, namely, Bhargava
Commission.
The
ruling in Panipat case' will not militate against this contention because that
was prior to October 1, 1974.
Again,
671 Sitaram case3 cannot affect this submission since there is no mention or
reference to the impact of Clause 5-A.
96.
The recommendations of the Bhargava Commission regarding sharing of excess
realisation from sale of free sugar between factories and the growers on 50:50
basis was adopted by the Government, as stated in Parliament on August 26,
1974. This was also given effect to, as is clear from the addition of Clause
5-A of Sugar-cane Control Order on September 25, 1974. Under the aforesaid
clause, excess realisations from sale of free sugar were to be shared on 50:50
basis between the producers and the growers. Further, Bhargava Commission, in
its report, has specifically stated that it will be unreasonable to deny the
industry a share in its excess realisation. Having regard to Schedule 11 under
Clause 5-A the L Factor is the unit cost based on minimum cane price and which
expressly includes the element of return.
97.
Even assuming that the change in the methodology after July 11, 1975 was
permissible and could be justified, it had to be such as would take into
account the change in law by reason of the introduction of Clause 5-A in the
Sugar-cane (Control) Order, 1966 issued under the Essential Commodities Act,
1955 and the statutory provision that the industry was entitled to retain 50
per cent of the excess realisation on sale of free sugar, 'which will give them
a reasonable margin for meeting their requirements' viz., industry's
commitments under bonus, gratuity, interest on borrowed capital and debentures,
dividend on preference shares, income tax and requirements for rehabilitation,
modernisation and expansion. Taking this into account, even if the changed
methodology was permissible, only 50 per cent of the excess realisation on sale
of free sugar can be mopped up.
98.
The Government, in opposition to this, would state as under:
"Clause
5-A of the Sugar-cane (Control) Order, 1966 provides for payment of additional
cane price only in case of surplus, arising, if any, from sales of both levy
and free sugar after adjustment of the unit cost of production ('L' Factor in
the formula specified in the Second Schedule of the order). The surplus may or
may not arise in the case of all sugar factories or during all seasons. It is
by no means a mandatory payment like minimum bonus. It is also wrong to suppose
that only surplus from realisations of free sale sugar are to be taken into
account under Clause 5-A. The 'A' Factor figuring in the formula refers to the
sales value of the entire production and not merely that of the free sale
quantities of production.
The
recommendations of the Bhargava Commission was made specifically with a view to
ensure that a part of the surplus is passed on to the cane growers. The sugar
factories would in any case retain the entire surplus for a statutory provision
like Clause 5-A.
The
determination of surplus is done after taking into account the sales value of
entire sugar production and not confined to free sale 672 production as per the
formula in the Second Schedule to the Sugar-cane (Control) Order.
It is
not correct to say that bonus, gratuity, interest on borrowed capital and debentures
were not taken into account in the determination of levy sugar price for
1974-75.
The
cost schedules recommended by the Tariff Commission Report, 1973 included,
among others, bonus, gratuity, interest on borrowed capital and debentures and
dividend on preference shares and depreciation. The determination of the levy
sugar prices by the Government was based on the cost schedules recommended by
the Tarrif Commission with suitable adjustment of the above mentioned
elements."
99. In
order to appreciate these contentions it is necessary to refer to the following
reports:
1.
Tariff Commission Report, 1973
2.
Bhargava Commission Inquiry Report, 1974
3. The
interim Report of the Bureau of Industrial Costs and Prices (June 1976) 100.
The relevant portions are extracted hereunder:
Tariff
Commission's Report, 1973:
"Para 3.4.10 : If the industry were fully controlled, it
would obviously be difficult for it to bear any part of the export loss as its
profit margin would be pegged at a certain level. In the case of sugar,
however, since there is at present a partial decontrol and the industry is
allowed to sell a part of its production the present figure for free sale is 30
per cent' it should be possible for the industry to recoup at least a part of
its export losses from the proceeds of free market sales.
Cost
Schedules for the future: The cost statement given in the previous paragraph is
based on the average duration and recovery of each zone for the five years
ending 1971-72.
Given
below is the cost schedule showing the cost under (i) constants, (ii)
variables, (iii) semi-variables and (iv) fixed charges.
This
is presented with the object of enabling Government to determine the quantum of
conversion charges including return for each future year for any (a) duration
and (b) recovery.
Para 9.26.2: We have not assessed the
profits made by the industry from its free market sales. When the price paid
for cane is something different from the minimum price which has gone into the
price structure of sugar there is considerable merit in the principle of
flexibility envisaged in the system of partial de-control. We, however, want to
stress the fact that the return of Rs 12.60 per quintal provided by us refers
to sugar as a whole and not to only levy sugar as such or to levy sugar."
101. In dealing with extra realisation from free market sales Bhargava
Commission observed as follows:
673
"2.14 The primary objective of the scheme is to provide incentives to cane
growers to enter into agreements with factories for supply of cane and to
fulfil their contracts. The scheme envisages various incentives including
provision of credit facilities and supply of inputs by factories and cane
growers' societies. However, the most important incentive is payment of an
additional price to those cane growers who enter into agreement for supply of
cane and fulfil them. It is proposed to find money for payment of the
additional price out of extra sales realisations of sugar factories. In years
of de-control or partial control ordinarily factories obtain prices for their
sugar over and above the prices to which they are entitled according to the
Tariff Commission Schedules. The scheme envisages sharing these extra sales
realisations between factory and cane growers." 102. In paragraph 2.15 the
details of the scheme were given as follows:
"SUGARCANE
SUPPLIES STABILISATION SCHEME 2.15 The details of the scheme are as follows:
(1) A
statutory minimum price for sugar-cane related to a basic recovery of 8.6 per
cent with a premium for every O. 1 per cent increase in recovery on
proportionality basis will be fixed by the Government of India.
(2)
The minimum price payable by individual factories will be fixed on the basis of
the recovery of the factory for the normal crushing period of the previous
season.
(3)
The statutory minimum price as fixed above shall be paid to all the cane
growers subject to clauses (18) and (19) of this scheme.
(4)
The factories shall share their extra sales realisation from sugar with the
cane growers who execute agreements for supply of cane and fulfil contracts.
(5)
The extra sales realisations shall be calculated according to the following
formula:
S=R-L
Where S stands for the amount shareable; R stands for the sales realisations
ex-factory excluding excise duty paid or payable to the factory by the purpose;
and L stands for sugar price as calculated on the basis of the statutory
minimum cane price and according to the Tariff Commission schedules in force at
the time. (In periods of control and partial control, L stands for the final
levy price of sugar fixed by Government.) (6) The sales realisations will be in
respect of the sugar produced during the season.
(7)
The sales realisations will comprise- (1) the actual amount realised up to and
inclusive of September 30; and 674 (ii) the estimated value of the unsold
stocks held at the end of September 30.
In
case (ii) the value of the stocks will be calculated at the average rate of the
sales made during the last fortnight of September.
(8)
The excess or shortfall in realisation from the actual sale of the unsold stock
of the season after September 30 shall be carried forward to and adjusted in
the extra sales realisations of the following season.
(9)
The extra realisation shall be divided equally between the factory and the cane
growers.......
103.
On the basis of the above recommendation Clause 5-A of the Sugar (Control)
Order was promulgated. The relevant part of Clause 5-A reads as follows:
"
5-A. Additional Price for Sugar-cane purchased on order after October 1, 1974:
(1)
Where a producer of sugar or his agent purchases sugar-cane, from a sugar-cane
grower during each sugar year, he shall, in addition to the minimum sugar-cane
price fixed under Clause 3, pay to the sugar-cane grower an additional price,
if found due in accordance with the provisions of the Second Schedule annexed
to this Order.
(2)
The Central Government or the State Government, as the case may be, may
authorise any person or authority, as it thinks fit, for the purpose of
determining the additional price payable by a producer of sugar under
sub-clause (1) and the person or authority, as the case may be, who determines
the additional price, shall intimate the same in writing to the producer of
sugar and the sugarcane grower connected with the supply of sugar-cane to such
producer of sugar.
(3)(a)
Any producer of sugar or sugar-cane grower, who is aggrieved by any decision of
the person or authority, referred to in sub- clause (2), may, within thirty
days from the date of communication of such decision under that sub-clause
appeal to the Central Government or the State Government, as the case may be:
Provided
that the Central Government or the State Government, as the case may be, may if
it is satisfied that the appellant had sufficient cause for not preferring the
appeal within the aforesaid period of thirty days, admit the appeal, if
presented within a further period of fifteen days.
(b)
The Central Government or the State Government, as the case may be, may after
giving an opportunity to the appellant to represent his case and after making
such further inquiry as may be necessary, pass such order as it thinks fit.
(c)
The decision of the person or authority referred to in subclause (2) where no
appeal is filed, and of the Central Government 675 or State Government, as the
case may be, where an appeal is filed, shall be final.
(4)
The additional price determined under sub-clause (2) shall be paid by the
producer of sugar to the sugar-cane grower, at such time and in such manner as
the Central Government or the State Government, as the case may be, may, from
time to time, direct.
(5) No
additional price determined under sub-clause (2) shall become payable by a
producer of sugar who pays a price higher than the minimum sugar-cane price
fixed under Clause 3 to the sugarcane grower:
Provided
that the price so paid shall in no case be less than the total price comprising
the minimum sugar-cane price fixed under Clause 3 and the additional price
determined under sub-clause (2).
Second
Schedule:
The
amount to be paid on account of additional price (per quintal of sugar-cane)
under Clause 5-A by a producer of sugar shall be computed in in accordance with
the following formula, namely:
R-I+2A+B
X= --------- RC Explanation in this formula:
1. 'X'
is the additional price in rupees per quintal of sugarcane payable by the
producer of sugar to the sugar-cane grower.
2. 'R'
is the amount in rupees of sugar produced during the sugar year excluding
excise duty paid or payable.
3. 'L'
is the amount in rupees of sugar required to be sold as levy calculated on the
basis of the levy price notified by Government as in force on 30th day of
September of each sugar year for sugar produced during that year, excluding
excise duty paid or payable.
4. 'A'
is the amount found payable for the previous year but not actually paid [vide
sub- clause (9)].
5. 'B'
is the excess or shortfall in realisation from actual sales of the unsold
stocks of sugar produced during the sugar year, as OD 30th day of September
[vide Item 7(ii) below] which is carried forward and adjusted in the sale
realisations of the following year.
6. 'C'
is the quantity in quintals of sugar-cane purchased by the producer of sugar
during the sugar year.
7. The
amounts 'R' and 'L' referred to in Items 2 and 3 shall be computed as under-
(1) the actual amount realised during the sugar year; and 676 (ii) the estimate
value of the unsold stocks of sugar held at the end of September 30, calculated
in regard to free sugar stocks at the average rate of sales made during the
fortnight 16th to 30th September and at the notified levy prices 'Prices as
applicable to levy stocks as on 30th September'.
Explanation.-
In this Schedule 'Sugar' means any form of sugar containing more than ninety
per cent sucrose." 104. It is true that Clause 5-A deals with additional
price payable to the sugar-cane grower. However, if the recommendations made by
the Bhargava Commission and the method of computation are taken into
consideration it will be clear that the producer of sugar will be entitled to
retain an amount equivalent to the amount paid to the cane grower under Clause
5-A. That amount cannot be taken into consideration for determination of the
price of levy sugar.
This
will be evident from paragraphs 2.17, 2.20, 2.21 and 2.39 of Chapter 11 of
Bhargava Commission Report. They are extracted below:
"2.17.
Statutory minimum prices for individual factories are fixed by the Government
of India in accordance with the quality formula' We have incorporated the
formula in the Scheme to ensure that the incentive to cane growers for
producing cane of better quality is retained.
In
discussing this formula earlier (in Part 11), we have made certain
recommendations which, in our opinion, will improve the effectiveness and
usefulness of the formula.
The
Scheme provides for a basic recovery of 8.5 per cent and the payment of
premium on proportionality basis. It also provides for the fixation of the
minimum prices payable by individual factories on the basis of the average of
the recovery of the previous normal crushing period of the factory. The reasons
for using the average recovery of the normal crushing period in preference to
the average recovery of the optimum period for this purpose have already been
stated.
2.20.
The provision of clause (6) about the sale realisations being in respect of the
sugar produced during the season is intended to ensure, as far as possible,
that cane growers who supplied the cane from which the sugar was produced
should benefit from the prices obtained for the sugar. The manner in which the
sales realisations should be calculated, presented a problem. It is necessary
that the additional price which may be payable to cane growers out of extra
realisation should be announced in October so that it may influence sowings of
cane and execution of agreements for supply of cane.
Keeping
this in view, it is necessary to calculate early in October the value of the
sugar produced during the season. About 70 per cent of sugar produced in a
season is ordinarily sold out by the end of September.
For
such stocks, the figures of actual realisations would be available by the end
of X X September.
2.21.
As regards the unsold stocks, the value thereof could be estimated in more than
one way on the basis of the market prices 677 prevailing at the end of
September, on the basis of the average of the sales of sugar up to the end of
September, on the basis of the average of the sales made during the last
fortnight of September, etc. The Scheme provides for an evaluation of the unsold
stock on the last basis mentioned. The problem, however, remained of accounting
for the difference between the estimated price and the actual subsequent
realisations from the stocks which remain unsold on September 30. This
difficulty has been overcome by the provisions for the differences being
carried forward to the next year for adjustment in the sugar sales
realisations.
2.39.
After considering all these facts we have decided that the extra realisations
on the sale of sugar be divided between the growers and the industry in the
ratio of 50:50. A provision of this effect has been made in clause (9) of the
Scheme. It should be mentioned that after deducting the tax obligations to be
borne by the industry, the actual accruals will be in the proportion of 70 to
the cane growers and 30 to the industry.
This
share of cane growers approximates the share of the cost of cane in the cost of
sugar." 105. For the regular production of sugar there must be regular
supply of sugar-cane.
106.
On this aspect of the matter, Justice E.S. Venkataramiah (as he then was)
observed in Writ Petition No. 432 etc. filed in the High Court of Karnataka as
follows:
"It
is well known that the availability of sugar-cane for manufacturing sugar
depends on several factors such as the probable price which the sugar-cane can
fetch when it is ready for harvest, the price of other foodstuffs which can be
grown on the land which has to be utilised for growing sugar-cane, the period
occupied in raising the sugarcane crop and the uncertain climatic conditions.
In order to maintain regular supply of sugar it is necessary to have regular
supply of sugarcane. The supply of sugar-cane depends upon the total average
brought under sugar-cane cultivation. The agriculturist should have the necessary
incentive to grow sugar-cane instead of some other crop and that is provided by
the Sugar-cane (Control) Order which authorises the Central Government to fix
the minimum price which the producer of sugar should pay to the cane grower on
a future date. This necessarily involves the determination of the minimum price
payable under Clause 3 of the Sugar- cane (Control) Order at the commencement
of the planting season. After the minimum price of sugar-cane is so fixed, at
the commencement of the sugar year [as defined in Clause 5-A of the Sugar-cane
(Control) Order], it is necessary for the Central Government to fix the price
payable for levy sugar and also determine the quantity of sugar which a
producer should supply to the Central Government or its nominee, to enable the
producer to arrange his programme of production well in advance and also to pay
extra price to the sugar-cane grower over and 678 above the price fixed under
Clause 3 of the Sugar-cane (Control) Order to attract supply of sufficient quantity
of sugar-cane to his factory, which of course he would be able to adjust
against the additional price payable under Clause 5-A after the close of the
sugar year. After the sugar year is over, the authority which is empowered to
determine the additional price would determine it in accordance with the
formula found in the Second Schedule and payment of additional price would be
made to the cane grower accordingly. At this stage the amount which the
producer can retain out of the extra realisation made by him would also be
known.
It is
significant that the Bhargava Commission recommended that the factory owner
should share the extra realisation with the cane grower. The expression 'to
share' means 'to participate in'. It, therefore, follows that a sum equivalent
to the amount paid by way of additional price would go to the benefit of the
producer. If that is the true legal position, the method adopted by the Central
Government in determining the price of levy sugar under the 1975 order would
have to be treated as faulty. No part of the extra realisation can be taken
into consideration while determining the price of levy sugar. It is no doubt
true that in Panipat case' the Supreme Court having regard to the law as it
stood then observed that it would be open to the Central Government to take
into consideration the extra realisation of a producer by the sale of levy free
sugar also while determining the price that has to be determined under Clause
3(3-C). I am of the view that the above view of the Supreme Court stands
superseded by Clause 5-A of the Sugar-cane (Control) Order which was introduced
subsequently. It is the duty of the Court to give effect to Clause 5-A of the
Sugar-cane (Control) Order without being influenced by any observations made by
the Supreme Court earlier when a similar clause was not in force. The case put
forward on behalf of the Central Government that even after the promulgation of
Clause 5-A it would be open to the Central Government to take into
consideration the extra realisation for the purpose of determining the price of
levy sugar under Clause 3(3-C), would be impracticable, because the
determination of price under Clause 3(3-C) cannot be postponed to a date
subsequent to the close of the sugar year. If that is allowed to be done, the
producer of sugar would be compelled to carry on production of sugar without
having an idea of the price that is likely to be determined by the Central
Government under Clause 3(3-C)." 107. We are in agreement with the above
observations since the approach to price determination is in the proper
perspective. It may also be added that the ruling in Sitaram case3 is silent as
to the impact of Clause 5-A of the Sugar-cane (Control) Order since what came
up for decision in that case was the correctness of the zonal fixation of
prices. Therefore, we uphold the contention of Mr Nariman that the changed
methodology adopted from July 11, 1975 was directly contrary to the
recommendations of Bhargava Commission which have come to be accepted by the
Government. Accordingly, we hold that the Government could not, in law, proceed
to a 679 determination of the levy price by mopping up 100 per cent of the
excess realisation of free sale sugar. This overlooks the fact that the
producer had become statutorily entitled to 50 per cent of such excess
realisation from October 1, 1974.
108.
We are unable to agree with the submissions advanced on behalf of the
Government that Clause 5-A deals only with the amount payable to the cane
grower and that it cannot have any relevance for determination of levy sugar.
If the determination of minimum price of sugar and fixation of the price of
levy sugar under quantity of sugar to be supplied by the producer are inter
connected, then they must be read as a whole and not separately as though each
is distinct.
While
fixing the price of levy sugar regard is had only to the minimum cane price as
spoken to under Section 3(3-C)(a).
This
minimum cane price is referable to clause (3) of Sugar- cane (Control) Order.
The additional price payable to the cane grower under Clause 5-A will arise
after the expiry of the sugar year. Sugar price will have to be met only from
the extra realisation made by the producer by the sale of sugar in free market
which will naturally be more than the levy price.
109.
In View of the above discussion, the impugned notifications except the one
dated November 28, 1974 cannot be upheld. The reason why we leave out the
notification dated November 28, 1974 is that the same came to be issued before
the new pricing policy was introduced We hereby direct the Union of India to
amend the notifications taking into account the liability of the manufacturers
under Clause 5-A of the Sugar-cane (Control) Order as regards cane price and
refix the price of levy sugar having regard to the factors mentioned in Section
3(3-C) of the Act. The Government will have time to issue the amended
notifications as directed above till December 31, 1993, 110 Though normally we
would have quashed the notifications mere quashing of the notifications would
lead to nebulous situation during the interregnum till the refixation of price
we are obliged to give the above direction. In this connection we may usefully
quote the following passage occurring at page 294 of Judicial Remedies in
Public Law by Dive Lewis:
"The
courts now recognise that the impact on the administration is relevant in the
exercise of their remedial jurisdiction. Quashing decisions may impose heavy
administrative burdens on the administration, divert resources towards
reopening decisions, and lead to increased and unbudgeted expenditure.
Earlier
cases took the robust line that the law had to be observed, and the decision
invalidated whatever the administrative inconvenience caused. The courts
nowadays recognise that such an approach is not always appropriate and may not
be in the wider public interest. The effect on the administrative process is
relevant to the courts' remedial discretion and may prove decisive." 111.
We may also add that the interests of the appellants will have to be measured
against the needs of good administration which include: the need 680 for speedy
finality in decision making, the public interest, the purpose of administrative
process and the need to consider substance not form.
112.
Pursuant to our interim orders bank guarantees have been furnished by the
appellants. 50 per cent of the same could be encashed by the respondents. The
other 50 per cent shall remain and the liabilities could be adjusted after the
determination of price as directed above.
113.
Accordingly, all the civil appeals, special leave petitions, writ petitions,
transfer petitions, transferred cases, interlocutory applications and CMPs will
stand as ordered.
Back